On the widely differing effects of free trade agreements: Lessons from twenty years of trade integration

01/16/2019

|

Scott L. Baier, Yoto V. Yotov, and Thomas Zylkin | Clemson University, Drexel University, University of Richmond

Abstract

We develop a novel two stage methodology that allows us to study the empirical determinants of the ex post effects of past free trade agreements (FTAs) as well as obtain ex ante predictions for the effects of future FTAs. We first identify 908 unique estimates of the effects of FTAs on different trading pairs for the years 1986–2006. We then employ these estimates as our dependent variable in a “second stage” analysis characterizing the heterogeneity in these effects. Interestingly, most of this heterogeneity (∼2/3) occurs within FTAs (rather than across different FTAs), with asymmetric effects within pairs (on exports vs. imports) also playing an important role. Our second stage analysis provides several intuitive explanations behind these variations. Even within the same agreement, FTA effects are weaker for more distant pairs and for pairs with otherwise high levels of ex ante trade frictions. The effects of new FTAs are similarly weaker for pairs with existing agreements already in place. In addition, we are able to relate asymmetries in FTA effects to each country’s ability to influence the other’s terms of trade. Out-of-sample predictions incorporating these insights enable us to predict direction-specific effects of future FTAs between any pair of countries. A simulation of the general equilibrium effects of TTIP demonstrates the significance of our methods.

1. Introduction

After a quarter-century of unprecedented trade integration, the world may be taking a momentary pause to re-evaluate the economic impact of free trade agreements. The past few years have seen the United Kingdom threaten to leave the E.U., the United States insist on the re-negotiation of NAFTA, and the high profile failures of TTIP and TPP- two would-be “mega deals” which together would have made 60% of the world’s production more interdependent by eliminating barriers to trade. While economic integration has always been controversial, a common theme in the current backlash against FTAs is the perception that past FTAs have not provided the economic benefits promised by policymakers at the time of their signing. Since the broader trend towards ever larger and more comprehensive trade deals seems unlikely to abate, the current moment thus offers an opportunity to take stock of the heterogeneous effects of past FTAs on bilateral trade flows ex post to see if these effects reflect the wisdom of established theory and to determine what lessons we can draw to better predict the effects of future FTAs ex ante.

The proliferation of new FTAs in recent years offers a useful historical lens for studying how trade agreements achieve liberalization that goes beyond the simple elimination of tariffs. Since 1986, there have been more than 350 new trade agreements notified to the WTO, which have differed in their aim, breadth, and scope. Broadly speaking, however, a shared objective of many of these agreements has been to achieve “deep” integration, i.e., economic integration that goes beyond tariff reduction and extends into policies that are more difficult for the econometrician to observe and to quantify. Leading econometric studies of the “average partial effect” of FTAs on trade, such as Baier & Bergstrand (2007) and Anderson & Yotov (2016), generally support this view, as the estimates they obtain appear too large to be explained by tariff reductions alone.2

As a result, those wishing to model the effects of FTAs ex ante face a fundamental problem: how to assess their initial, partial equilibrium impact on bilateral trade. If FTAs affect trade only through tariffs, this partial effect could be computed directly (assuming a constant elasticity). However, in combination, the small current levels of tariffs and the large FTA estimates from the existing literature support the conclusion that the effects of FTAs on bilateral trade go far beyond the simple elimination of tariffs. To allow for such possibilities, a growing number of researchers use econometric estimates of the ex post effects of existing FTAs (often just a single average estimate) as a proxy for the effects of future agreements.3However, aside from variation in tariffs (or, more nebulously, in “non-tariff measures”, NTMs), few theoretically-grounded arguments exist for why these partial effects might differ systematically across different agreements.

Accordingly, the main goal of this paper is to develop methods and hypotheses that will identify meaningful, theoretically-motivated sources of variation for predicting the effects of trade deals ex ante. In particular, we pursue a “two stage” estimation procedure for quantifying and studying heterogeneity in the effects of FTAs, using data on trade and production for 70 countries over the period 1986–2006. In a first stage, we expand on the methods of Baier & Bergstrand (2007) and Bergstrand et al. (2015) to obtain agreement-specific effects for each FTA signed during the period, as well as “direction-of-trade”-specific estimates for each member pairing within a given agreement. This stage of the analysis delivers a total of 908 direction-specific, widely-varying FTA estimates, which we then use as dependent variables in a second stage that studies the determinants of the variance in the FTA estimates.

To help explain this heterogeneity, we seek guidance from theory. Specifically, we exploit the basic structure of a standard multi-country trade model to examine two novel sources of variation. First, to the extent that some trade frictions are induced by trade policies and domestic regulations, pairs of countries with higher levels of trade frictions ex ante should have more potential for larger FTA partial effects ex post. Second, drawing on the influential “terms of trade” arguments of Bagwell and Staiger, 1999Bagwell and Staiger, 2005, countries with less “market power” over their own terms of trade should grant relatively smaller concessions when they sign FTAs, because they are likely already close to their “politically optimal” set of trade policies. To operationalize these insights, we introduce two indices: (i) a comprehensive index of “pre-FTA trade barriers”, which we obtain naturally from our econometric first stage model, and (ii) a simulated measure of each member of an agreement’s “terms of trade sensitivity”, which, to emphasize the connection with the theories of Bagwell & Staiger, we also refer to as “revealed market power”. Our analysis finds robust support for both of these hypotheses.

We also confirm two other intuitively plausible hypotheses that can account for a fraction of the observed heterogeneity. First, countries with prior trade agreements already in place tend to have weaker partial effects from any subsequent agreements. Second, even after controlling for the level of existing trade frictions, FTA partial effects are weaker for countries which are further apart geographically. This may be because more distant countries are less sensitive to changes in trade policies (as emphasized in Baier et al., 2018) or perhaps because they find it more difficult to coordinate on deeper integration because of weaker cultural affinities.

One other variable that has been highlighted in the broader literature on FTAs also draws our interest. Following the work of Kehoe & Ruhl (2013) on the “new goods” margin of trade – as well as subsequent work by Kehoe et al. (2015) – we test whether countries that trade a relatively small range of products ex ante have more potential for “explosive” trade creationafter the signing of an FTA. Interestingly, we find that the number of products trade ex anteis, if anything, positively related to the amount of trade creation ex post, seemingly contradicting these earlier findings. Two remarks help reconcile this discrepancy. First, to the extent that a low traded goods margin manifests itself in a “gravity” framework as high trade costs, our comprehensive index of “pre-FTA trade barriers” already takes this margin into account. Second, the distinction between “across-” versus “within-” agreement heterogeneity is again important here. In particular, when we restrict our focus to asymmetric FTA effects within the same pair of countries – better approximating the case study design used in Kehoe & Ruhl (2013) and Kehoe et al. (2015) – we do find that a low traded goods margin helps predict asymmetries in trade creation.

In light of recent trends towards larger multilateral trade blocs, an especially appealing aspect of our two stage approach is that we can easily narrow our focus to heterogeneous effects that might occur within individual agreements.4 Interestingly, we find that variation in FTA effects across different agreements (i.e., the difference between NAFTA and Mercosur) explains only about one-third of the variation in our first stage estimates of FTA effects. Of the remaining two-thirds, which are due to “within agreement” heterogeneity, almost half (i.e., almost one-third of the total) is due to asymmetric effects “within pairs”. With the exception of prior agreements, our key variables of interest remain relevant when we limit attention to heterogeneity within agreements. We are also specifically able to relate asymmetries in trade creation within pairs to differences in market power, as would be predicted by terms-of-trade theory.

We subject these insights to a battery of other controls that may be plausibly linked to trade creation, including “gravity” relationships, depth of the agreements, factor endowmentdifferences, institutional frictions to trade, and ex ante tariff policies. These additional regressions reveal several useful auxiliary findings. For example, we find that our preferred second stage model significantly outperforms observed tariffs in explaining the heterogeneity in our FTA estimates, especially when we consider heterogeneity “within agreements” and “within pairs”. Information on factor endowments and/or institutional development similarly only seems useful for predicting the heterogeneity that occurs across agreements; they are silent as to why the same agreement could have different effects for different members. We do, however, find robust evidence that FTA effects are larger for countries with larger economic size (GDP).

By design, our two stage approach is well-suited for developing and validating a model for making ex ante predictions. Drawing on the machine learning literature, we use an “out of sample” prediction analysis to test if an empirical model fitted from the first stage estimates of one set of agreements can reliably predict the partial effects found in the excluded agreements.5 As an illustration, we use the predictive model developed from this out-of-sample analysis to generate unique, direction-of-trade-specific predicted partial effects of a hypothetical revived TTIP on trade between the U.S. and E.U. Compared with an alternate scenario in which TTIP has the same partial effect on all TTIP trade flows (as is typically assumed in other analyses), we find that allowing for heterogeneous partial effects has important consequences for how TTIP affects welfare, which follow directly from the empirical insights we document in the second stage analysis. In this way, our three-part approach offers a cohesive methodology for studying and predicting heterogeneous effects of FTAs: the first stage creates preliminary objects of interest, the second stage provides a thorough empirical deconstruction, and the third part demonstrates a novel method for making ex ante predictions that highlights and validates the practical usefulness of the first two parts.

Naturally, our approach is complementary to the prevailing, non-econometric methods that have been used to model the effect of trade policies ex ante. Because FTAs have shifted their focus away from tariffs, applied work in the CGE literature increasingly aims to quantify the impact of non-tariff provisions of FTAs on so-called “non-tariff barriers”. However, as discussed in Fugazza & Maur (2008), because of the complexity of these issues, even the best-possible estimates of non-tariff barriers must be interpreted with caution and model results based on these estimates may be highly fragile to minor variations in methodology. Our methods admittedly lack the specificity of a fully-specified CGE framework. Nonetheless, we are able to identify several broad sources of variation in FTA effects that have been previously overlooked, have strong theoretical and intuitive appeal, and appear to have robust support in the data.

Lastly, because we allow FTA effects to differ by agreement, we also contribute to a longstanding literature that has examined the effects of individual agreements. This literature begins with the seminal work of Tinbergen (1962), who found only small effects for the Benelux and British Commonwealth preference arrangements, and also includes other influential studies by Frankel & Wei (1997) and Carrère (2006), who allow for differences across several major modern regional trading blocs. Methodologically, the most related work in this area is Kohl (2014), who observes that FTA effects may differ based on WTO membership and on the institutional quality of an agreement. By and large, these studies have not found that most FTAs have increased trade. For example, Kohl (2014) finds only 27% of FTAs have had positive and significant effects on trade. We, however, find positive effects for a majority (57%) of the agreements in our study. This could be for three reasons. First, we follow the econometric recommendations of Santos Silva & Tenreyro (2006) in using Poisson PML, as opposed to OLS, in order to account for heteroskedasticity of trade data and to be able to use the information contained in zero trade flows. Second, we include consistently-measured internal trade flows, which enable us to capture the possibility that increases in trade between liberalizing countries may actually be at the expense of internal trade.6 Third, bilateral trade flows may not instantaneously respond to the implementation of an FTA. To account for the phasing-in of different provisions and other adjustments that may accompany FTAs, we allow agreements to have lagged effects that accumulate over time.

The following section describes the first stage estimation procedure. Section 3 adds details on how we construct our data and key variables. Section 4 summarizes our first stage FTA estimates. These estimates are then used as the dependent variables in the second stage analysis, which is contained in Section 5Section 6 uses the insights from the second stage to forecast the effects of TTIP. Finally, Section 7 adds concluding remarks.

2. Decomposition of FTA Effects

This section describes how we recover heterogeneous estimates of the effects of FTAs. We start with a brief review of the structural gravity model, which delivers an estimating equation for the “average partial effect” of an FTA. We then discuss how to decompose this average effect into successively nested layers of heterogeneity, starting with the level of the individual agreement and then allowing for an increasingly more detailed heterogeneity within agreements as well.

2.1. Structural gravity

Our starting point is a simple, generalized version of the “structural gravity” equation, as originally derived by Anderson (1979) and as popularized by Eaton & Kortum (2002) and Anderson & van Wincoop (2003) and subsequently extended to the panel dimension by Baier & Bergstrand (2007).7 Let Xij denote the value of exports from an origin country i to a destination country j. The gravity equation for these trade flows is

(1)Xij=Aiwi−θτij−θ∑lAlwl−θτlj−θEj.

In (1), Ej is the total expenditure by purchasers in j on goods across all different origins (including goods produced domestically in j). The share of j’s expenditure allocated specifically to products from any one origin i is then directly dependent on the following three factors: Ai, the overall quality of the production technologies available in iwi, the wage in i; and τij, the “iceberg” trade cost required to send goods from i to j. Goods from different origins are assumed to be imperfectly substitutable; therefore, the effects of production costsand trade costs on trade are subject to a constant trade elasticity θ > 1. Importantly, all cost factors only weigh on trade relative to the overall degree of competition in j’s import market, which is accounted for via the summation term in the denominator of (1). Noting that this summation term is specific to the importing country (because it sums across all origins), a more compact way of writing (1) is

(2)Xij=Aiwi−θτij−θPj−θEj,

where Pjθ = ∑iAiwiθτijθ. As noted by Anderson & van Wincoop (2003)Pjθ serves as a useful aggregate of all bilateral trade costs faced by consumers in importer j.8 Writing the structural gravity equation as in (2) – with distinct ij, and i-by-j components – lends itself naturally to deriving a “fixed effects” estimation equation for trade flows, as we demonstrate below.

2.2. Panel econometric implementation

From an empirical perspective, our primary object of interest is the combined trade frictions parameter τijθ. We are not, however, interested in the general determinants of trade frictions -e.g., geographical distance, historical affinities, etc. – which have been widely explored in the broader gravity literature.9 Rather, we wish to focus on how FTAs have shaped changes in τijθ over time. More specifically, we aim to shed light on how different agreements have had very different effects on τijθ and, furthermore, how changes in τijθ may vary widely even within the same agreement.

Our first step in this direction is to follow Baier & Bergstrand (2007) in deriving a panel implementation of (2) that permits identification of an average FTA effect across all the agreements in our sample. To ease this derivation, we first add a time subscript, t, as well as an error term, εijt, and re-write (2) in exponential form:

(3)Xij,t=explnAi,twi,t−θ+lnEj,tPj,t−θ+lnτij,t−θ+εij,t.

Next, use the following generic functional form for the trade costs term lnτijtθ

lnτij,t−θ=Zijδ+β1FTAij,t+β2FTAij,t−5+uij,t,

where Zij can be thought of a set of time-invariant controls for the general level of trade costs between i and j with coefficient vector δ. For more traditional gravity applications, the contents of Zij would normally be specified to include geographical and/or historical ties between countries, as discussed above. For our purposes, however, the main variables of interest are FTAijt, a 0/1 indicator for if i and j belong to a common free trade agreement at time t, and FTAijt−5, a 5 year lag of FTAijt. The inclusion of this lagged term accounts for the possibility that FTA effects may “phase-in” over time, as has been previously shown by such papers as Baier &Bergstrand (2007) and Anderson & Yotov (2016).10

A concern that arises is that there are components of Zij that are unobserved and correlated with FTAs, and not accounting for these factors will result in biased coefficient estimates. A key insight from Baier & Bergstrand (2007) is that specific knowledge of δ is neither necessary nor sufficient in order to obtain consistent estimates of the effects of FTAs. Instead, drawing on standard panel estimation techniques described in Wooldridge (2002)Baier & Bergstrand (2007) recommend using pair-specific fixed effects in place of Zijδ, such that the time dimension of the panel identifies the (average) causal effect of FTAs on trade. With this same strategy in mind, our baseline specification for estimating the average effect of FTAs on trade barriers becomes

(4)Xij,t=expηi,t+ψj,t+γij¯+β1FTAij,t+β2FTAij,t−5+εij,t.

Here, ηit and ψjt are, respectively, time-varying exporter- and importer- fixed effects meant to absorb the lnAitwitθ and lnEjt/Pjtθ terms in (3), which are endogenous and cannot be observed directly. In addition, ηit and ψjt also effectively control for all country-level factors on the exporter and on the importer side, respectively. γij¯ is a (symmetric) pair-wise fixed effect that strips out all time-invariant determinants of trade barriers between i and j.11 Lastly, we treat the additive residual term εijt as both reflecting measurement error in trade values as well as now also absorbing the error term in lnτijtθ above. Following the recommendations of Santos Silva and Tenreyro, 2006Santos Silva and Tenreyro, 2011, we estimate (4) – as well as all subsequent specifications described in this section – using Poisson Pseudo-maximum Likelihood (“PPML”).12

We obtain our final baseline specification for estimating the effects of FTAs by incorporating the methods of Bergstrand et al. (2015), who argue that FTA estimates based on specification (4) may be biased upward because they may be capturing the effects of globalization. Adapting a related idea from Yotov (2012), the simple adjustment proposed by Bergstrand et al. (2015) is to explicitly control for the effects of globalization in the gravity model by introducing a set of globalization dummies.

Applied to our setting, this adjustment results in the following econometric model:

(5)Xij,t=expηi,t+ψj,t+γij¯+β1FTAij,t+β2FTAij,t−5+∑tbt+εij,t,

where the added term ∑tbt is a set of dummies that equal 1 for international tradeobservations (as opposed to internal trade, Xii) at each time t. The coefficients on these time-varying border dummies, the bt’s, capture the process of globalization over time, as all countries trade more with each other and less with their own internal markets.

The average “total” (or “cumulative”) effect of FTAs on trade after accounting for phasing-in can be constructed as β ≡ β1 + β2. The specific interpretation of β can be described in one of two ways. From a strictly econometric point of view, β is the total average partial effect of an FTA on bilateral trade flows, noting that FTAs also influence trade through the country-specific terms ηit and ψjt. A second, more structural interpretation is that β gives the average treatment effect of an FTA specifically on “trade costs” -i.e., its effect on the lnτijtθterm in (3). To ease this latter interpretation, note that the combined term expγij¯+bt+β1FTAij,t+β2FTAij,t−5 describes the predicted level of τijtθ in place between countries i and j at time t. To comment more thoroughly on the identification of β, note that increases in trade between i and j do not translate directly to implied reductions in the trade cost term lnτijtθ. Instead, due to the presence of the time-varying exporter and importer fixed effects, the impact of FTAs is only identifiable when trade increases between iand j relative to each country’s trade with all other partners. Importantly, and consistent with theory, the set of outside partners for each country includes the value for Xii, the value of sales to one’s own market, or “internal trade”. We regard accounting for internal trade as a key feature of our empirical approach. As documented empirically in Dai et al. (2014), including internal trade in the estimation should lead to larger, more precise estimates of FTA effects.13

2.3. Allowing for FTA heterogeneity

With the wide adoption of Baier & Bergstrand’s methods, most estimates of the effects of FTAs in the prior literature generally find positive and significant “average” results.14However, for the purposes of policy analysis, an obvious weakness of estimating an “average” FTA effect is that the effects of a given agreement may be substantially different from the average; thus, it may not be appropriate to apply an average estimate of the effects of all existing FTAs for making ex ante predictions about the effects of specific FTAs. To capture and analyze this potential heterogeneity in FTA effects, we expand on the initial specification shown in (5) in three successive steps:

First, we consider a specification where FTA effects are allowed to vary at the level of the underlying agreement, similar to the approach taken in Kohl (2014)15:

(6)Xij,t=expηi,t+ψj,t+γij¯+∑Aβ1,AFTAij,t+∑Aβ2,AFTAij,t−5+∑tbt+εij,t,

where we allow for a distinct average partial effect –βA ≡ β1, A + β2, A– for each individual agreement, using superscript A to index by agreement and also allowing for agreement-specific lags. This initial refinement allows us to make useful statements about which FTAs in our sample have been more successful than others about promoting trade. However, it is silent about the possibility that the same agreement may not affect all countries involved in exactly the same way.

Second, we allow for further heterogeneity at the level of each trading pair within an agreement. For example, we allow Sweden’s accession to the E.U. in 1995 to have different effects on its trade barriers with Germany vs. its trade barriers with the U.K. The resulting specification is

(7)Xij,t=exp(ηi,t+ψj,t+γij¯+∑A∑p∈Aβ1,A:pFTAij,t+∑A∑p∈Aβ2,A:pFTAij,t−5+∑tbt)+εij,t,

where each p ∈ A is a pair of countries (ij) belonging to agreement A, counting (ij) and (ji) as the same pair. βA:p ≡ β1, A:p + β2, A:p then gives us a corresponding set of agreement-pair-specificFTA estimates.

Third, we consider the possibility that, even within a given pair, an FTA may not affect trade in both directions symmetrically. For this last refinement, let d ∈ A denote a unique “directional pair” of countries i,j→ belonging to agreement A, where the notation i,j→refers specifically to the effect on trade flows where i is the exporter and j is the importer. We thus estimate two effects for each agreement-pair, one for each direction of trade. In addition, since FTAs no longer affect each partner symmetrically within a given pair, we now also introduce an asymmetric pair fixed effect “γij→”, which varies by direction as well. We then have the following econometric model:

(8)Xij,t=exp(ηi,t+ψj,t+γij→+∑A∑d∈Aβ1,A:dFTAij,t+∑A∑d∈Aβ2,A:dFTAij,t−5+∑tbt)+εij,t,

βA:d ≡ β1, A:d + β2, A:d then gives us a unique set of direction-specific estimates which we will soon use for our “second stage” analysis of the empirical determinants of trade integration.

Before proceeding further, we pause to clarify two important details. First, the heterogeneous FTA estimates that will be obtained from specifications (6), (7), and (8) should be interpreted with care. While Baier & Bergstrand (2007) has emerged as the standard method for consistently estimating the average treatment effect of FTAs, the same cannot be said when we pull apart our average “β” to obtain increasingly more finely-grained coefficients, which we should regard as being estimated with at least some unobserved error. Instead, our preferred method draws on the suggested approach of Lewis & Linzer (2005): even if the individual βA:d’s we estimate from our empirical specifications contain some unobserved noise, we can still investigate heterogeneity in the causal effects of FTAs by using a “second stage” regression analysis to extract some useful signals from that noise.16

Second, our desire to allow for individual lagged effects creates an additional complication because it is not possible to estimate 5 year lagged effects for the agreements that form within the last 5 years. While we could drop these later agreements from the sample, doing so effectively discards the useful information in the contemporaneous FTA effects β1, Aβ1,A:p, and β1, A:d. Instead, our preferred way of addressing this issue is to use the direction-specific estimates (the βA:d’s) from the first 15 years of data to estimate the following auxiliary regression

(9)β2,A:d=π0+π1β1,A:d+υA:d,

such that we may then infer the needed remaining lags using β2, A:d = π0 + π1β1, A:d. We use the same coefficients to infer missing values for β2, A’s and β2, A:p’s where needed.17

3. Data construction

This section describes the sources and the construction of the data with emphasis on several specially constructed indices that are theoretically motivated and used as key regressors in our second stage analysis in Section 5. These indices include our novel measures of “pre-FTA trade barriers” and “revealed market power”, as well as the “new goods” margin of Kehoe & Ruhl (2013).

3.1. Trade and FTA data for first stage analysis

3.1.1. Trade

We construct a data set with information on manufacturing production and trade for a sample of 70 countries over the twenty year period 1986–2006.18 Table A.1 of the Data Appendix lists the countries included. For computational reasons, we combine 17 countries which do not form any FTAs during the period into a single “Rest of the World” aggregate region. Thus, in the end, we arrive at a balanced panel of 53 trading regions observed over the 21 year period 1986–2006.19 Our primary source for bilateral trade flows is UN COMTRADE. Since partner countries tend to report different values for same trade flow, we generally use the mean of reported values when possible. If either country fails to report a value, we use the non-missing value.

An important feature of our dataset is that it includes values for “internal trade” flows (a.k.a. “domestic sales”). To construct internal trade observations, we combine data on industry-level gross output from two main sources: the CEPII TradeProd database and UNIDO IndStat. We have selected both the sample of countries and the period of study in order to achieve the widest possible use of the available production data from these sources. Since production values in TradeProd are largely taken from earlier versions of UNIDO IndStat – and further augmented using the World Bank “Trade, Production, and Protection” database by Nicita & Olarreaga (2007)– we generally use TradeProd to provide production data for earlier years and data from UNIDO to fill in later years where needed.20 We also cross-check against the World Bank data to fill in some additional missing values from the beginning of the period. We then construct internal trade values as the difference between the value of a country’s gross output and the value of its total exports to other markets. In some isolated cases, however, it is not possible to calculate internal trade values because the production data is either missing or implies a negative value for internal trade. We address these issues in a series of steps. First, we apply linear interpolation between non-missing values whenever possible. Second, if values are negative or missing only for a particular industry, we apply the average share of expenditure spent on domestic output by that country on other (non-missing) industries. Finally, we extrapolate any remaining missing production values at the beginning or end of the sample using the evolution of that country’s industry-level exports.21

3.1.2. Free trade agreements

Our starting point for FTA data is the set of FTAs used in Baier & Bergstrand (2007). We update and cross-check this data against information available via the WTO’s website as well as the NSF-Kellogg Database on Economic Integration Agreements. Table A.2 of the Data Appendix provides a complete summary of the agreements included in our study. Overall, our FTA data cover 65 different agreements, including 8 multilateral trading blocs, 32 bilateral FTAs, and 25 agreements between multilateral blocs and outside partners.22Within these 65 agreements, there are 455 different agreement-pairs, counting as separate any instance where two countries that are already joined via a prior agreement become part of a second agreement (e.g., Canada and the U.S. in the case of NAFTA). Since we estimate two effects per agreement-pair, we would ordinarily be able to estimate 2 ⋅ 455 = 910 distinct FTA effects in total. However, because Iceland never exports to Romania before the signing of the EFTA-Romania FTA in 1993, we are not able to obtain a directional estimate for EFTA-Romania on Iceland-Romania exports. We therefore drop the Iceland-Romania pair from the latter two sets of estimates, leaving us with 454 pair-specific estimates and 908 direction-specific estimates to be used in the subsequent analysis.

3.2. Key covariates for second stage analysis

3.2.1. FTA estimates

To construct the dependent variable for the second-stage analysis of the determinants of the impact of FTAs, we combine the estimates of the current and lagged effects of FTAs. The Online Appendix offers robustness experiments with alternative treatments of the lags.

3.2.2. Pre-FTA trade barriers

As originally observed by Baier & Bergstrand (2007), the main advantage of using a panel specification with pair fixed effects to identify the effects of trade policies is that the pair fixed effects effectively absorb all bilateral trade frictions in the cross-section. Importantly, this includes any “unobservable” component of trade costs, which otherwise would enter the error term and potentially lead to inconsistent estimates. Therefore, the pair fixed effect γij→in (8) contains potentially very useful information about the full level of ex ante trade barriersbetween any potential FTA pair, including any unobservable trade costs. However, because γij→ is direction-specific, and because of collinearity between γij→ and the exporter and importer fixed effects ηit and ψjt, we cannot directly interpret the values for γij→ we recover from the estimation as reflecting “trade barriers” (i.e., the τijθ’s). In principle, however, we can identify the average trade level of ex ante trade barriers for trade between a given pair ij by imposing symmetry on the γij→’s. In practice, we can perform the following regression:

(10)Xij,t=exp(ηi,t+ψj,t+γij¯+∑tbt+∑A∑d∈Aβ˜1,A:dFTAij,t+∑A∑d∈Aβ˜2,A:dFTAij,t−5)+εij,t,

where the tilde superscript on the set of the partial FTA effects β˜1,A:d and β˜2,A:d reflects that fact that we are constraining these to be the same as we estimated previously from (7) using directional fixed effects. The γij¯’s are similarly constrained to be symmetric within pairs.

The combined term “γij¯+bt−1” then provides a measure of the average level of trade barriers between i and j in the year before the signing of an FTA at time t. Since γij¯+bt−1 is an inverse measure of pre-FTA trade frictions between i and j, we expect that it should enter with a negative sign in the second stage analysis. Because it is an “inclusive” measure of these frictions, it can plausibly control for a variety of different obstacles to trade that could potentially be eliminated by an FTA and would be difficult to capture otherwise, including idiosyncratic differences in domestic regulations that inhibit trade (as emphasized in Baier & Bergstrand, 2007), the trade-muting effects of uncertainty over future trade policies (c.f., Limão, 2016Sec. 4.3), as well as each country’s unilateral incentives to impose restrictive trade policies ex ante. Furthermore, since this measure holistically controls for the full magnitude of ex ante trade barriers between a given pair of countries, we can then also include standard proxies for trade costs (ln DIST, COLONY, etc.) and these will now in turn give us more specific inferences about the roles these variables play in explaining the first stage partial effects (rather than also reflecting the role these variables play in determining the magnitude of initial trade barriers). In our empirical analysis, we will simply refer (with some abuse in terminology) to the combined term “γij¯+bt−1” as our “first stage pair fixed effect”. Note also that, in the year before an FTA, we have that τij,t−1−θ=eγij¯+bt−1.

3.2.3. Revealed market power

Despite its inclusiveness, a key weakness of the pre-FTA trade barriers index just-described is that it is strictly symmetric and does not allow us to speak to why we should observe asymmetries in trade creation within agreements. One plausible theoretical reason for asymmetries are through differences in each country’s terms of trade-related incentives for restricting trade ex ante. We therefore also introduce a measure of each FTA country’s “terms of trade sensitivity” (or “revealed market power”), which we will use to examine whether asymmetries in our estimated FTA effects can be rationalized based on terms-of-trade theory.

We derive this latter index as follows. First, we take a given set of FTA-signing countries in the year before they entered the agreement (e.g., the U.S., Canada, and Mexico in 1993). We then use a standard multi-country general equilibrium model (described further in Section 6) to simulate the change in each country’s “terms of trade” as a result of a symmetric reduction in trade barriers (i.e., a common “partial effect” β¯) applied to all trade flows within this set of countries. The index we use for the change in a country’s terms of trade is

(11)ToT^A:j=w^jP^j,

which, following Anderson & Yotov (2016), uses the ratio of the change in a country’s producer price w^j to the change in its purchasing price P^j (which also gives the change in its real wage).23 We repeat this process for every FTA in the sample, using the same common partial effect each time (we use the overall average partial effect estimated from (5), β¯=0.293) and a (typical) trade elasticity of θ = 4. This procedure will deliver ToT^A:j’s corresponding to each country j in every agreement A in our sample, which are directly comparable with one another and should not be systematically related to the partial effects estimated from the first stage, other than for the reasons we are investigating.24Furthermore, similar to our (symmetric) “Pre-FTA Trade Barriers” index, ToT^A:j is also a relatively “inclusive” measure of terms of trade incentives in that it plausibly reflects incentives to use other trade policies aside from tariffs.

The connection to theory follows from what the resulting ToT^A:j indices reveal about the sensitivity of a country’s terms of trade with respect to the trade barriers of its prospective FTA partners. As elementary trade theory suggests, in the absence of a trade agreement, countries with more ability to depress the producer prices of other countries with their trade policy decisions -i.e., more “market power” – have stronger incentives to set high policy barriers to trade ex anteBagwell & Staiger (1999) then show that, to achieve an “efficient” trade agreement, both countries must fully internalize the externalities their trade policies impose on the other’s terms of trade, such that countries with more market power will always make larger trade concessions in any efficient agreement.25 Our ToT^A:j measure captures this idea by revealing the differential responses of each member’s terms of trade to a common reduction in trade barriers. For a country with relatively low market power, the computed values of ToT^A:j will be relatively high, since the increase in their producer price w^j from a symmetric trade agreement will be large relative to changes in producer prices in their prospective partners, which enter the ToT^ index through the change in the buyer price index P^j.26 For a high market power country, it is the opposite, since – for a reciprocal agreement – its own price levels are relatively less affected. Thus, guided by theory, we expect the FTA partial effects we estimate – the βA:d’s from the first stage – to be larger when the importing country’s ToT^A:j is low.27

Of course, the original theory of Bagwell & Staiger (1999) is a theory of multilateral tariff negotiations via the WTO rather than a theory of FTAs per se. Since Bagwell & Staiger (1999)’s seminal contribution, several subsequent frameworks help to clarify the applicability of terms-of-trade theory to our setting with FTAs. First, even if we expect WTO members to have already achieved their globally efficient trade policy levels, Bagwell & Staiger (2005)demonstrate that countries which subsequently negotiate preferential FTAs still have a “bilateral opportunism” incentive to lower their trade policies further in order to distort world prices to their mutual advantage. Second, Staiger & Sykes (2011) and Staiger (2012) have shown how terms-of-trade theory may be applied to non-tariff barriers when tariff policies are constrained by the WTO.28 Third, Limão (2007) illustrates how FTA provisions on “non-trade objectives” (such as intellectual property rights, security cooperation, and labor and environmental standards) create additional avenues for low-market power countries to compensate high-market power countries for increased market access that are not available though the WTO. Under any of these frameworks, the balance of trade concessions within FTAs should flow from countries with more ability to manipulate the terms of trade to countries with less, consistent with the hypothesis stated above.

3.2.4. New goods margin

For some specifications, we also follow Kehoe & Ruhl (2013) in accounting for the possibility that country pairs that trade a smaller range of product varieties ex ante have more potential for “explosive” trade growth ex post. The measure of the number of traded products we use is the Hummels-Klenow decomposition of the “extensive margin” of trade Hummels & Klenow, 2005), using Kehoe & Ruhl (2013)’s (pair specific) “least traded goods” cutoff to determine whether to count a variety as traded or not. Specifically, the extensive margin of trade from i to j at time t − 1 (i.e., the year before an agreement) is constructed as

(12)Ext.Marginij,t−1=∑p∈ΩijXWj,t−1∑p∈ΩWjXWj,t−1.

XWjt−1 is the volume of trade that each importer j receives from the world at time t − 1. Each variety p in (12) is an 5 digit SITC product variety, obtained from COMTRADE and assembled using the same procedures described above for aggregate trade. As in Kehoe & Ruhl (2013)p is only assigned to the “traded goods set” Ωij if, when varieties are sorted by trade volume, bilateral trade volume in p lies above the 10th percentile. (12) thus gives us a flexible measure of the share of products exported from i to j, weighted by each product’s contribution to j’s total imports.

4. Summarizing FTA estimates

Using the first stage econometric specifications presented in Eqs.(5)(6)(7)(8), we generate 4 distinct sets of FTA estimates. Each set of estimates consists of current and lagged FTA effects. For expositional simplicity, the presentation in this section focuses on “total” FTA effects (i.e., the sum of the corresponding current and lagged FTA estimates). Following Larch et al. (2017), all first stage standard errors are “three-way” clustered by exporter, importer, and year.29

4.1. Average FTA estimate

We start by briefly discussing the average (across all agreements and pairs) total FTA effect that we obtain based on (5). This specification corresponds to the standard approach in the literature and is the easiest to describe: we estimate an average total FTA effect of β = 0.293, with a standard error of 0.105 (p = 0.005). This estimate yields the interpretation that, on average, FTAs have a partial effect of (e0.293 − 1) ∗ 100 = 34.0% on trade flows. Alternatively, using a typical value for the trade elasticity of θ = 4 in combination with gravity theory, our average estimate implies a 1−e−0.2934∗100=7.1% average decline in bilateral trade frictions.30

4.2. Inferring lags for later agreements

As noted, we would like to extract as much information as possible from our first stage estimates of later agreements while still acknowledging that “phasing-in” is an important component of FTA-related trade growth. After first obtaining estimates of β1, A:d and β1, A:dfrom (8), we subsequently estimate (using (9))

(13)β2,A:d=0.141+0.201⋅β1,A:d+υA:d.

With “robust” standard errors, both of the estimates in (13) are highly statistically significant (p < 0.001 in both cases.) Importantly, in addition to allowing us to include later agreements in our analysis, this method also generates results that contribute to the literature on the timing of FTA effects (c.f., Magee, 2008Baier et al., 2014). In particular, our finding that π0 > 0 implies that lagged effects of FTAs are more likely to be positive than their corresponding initial effects. Likewise, π1 > 0 suggests that agreements with larger initial effects should also be expected to have larger lagged effects.

4.3. Agreement-specific estimates

Our estimates of agreement-specific effects obtained by estimating (6) are shown in Table 1, grouped by sign and significance and listed in descending order. As an alternative means of conveying the heterogeneity in these effects, we also offer a graphical depiction in Fig. 1, which presents the distribution of our estimates with their associated 95% confidence bounds.31 Several features of these results stand out. First, not all the agreement-specific effects that we estimate are positive and statistically significant. We find that 38.5% of our estimates (25/65) are statistically insignificant at the p = 0.05 significance level, and 7.6% of our point estimates (5/65) are negative and significant. Nonetheless, the fact that we find positive, statistically significant partial effects for the majority (53.9%) of the agreements in our sample is re-assuring given the more mixed results found in the prior literature. Kohl (2014), for example, only obtains positive and significant effects for 27% of the agreements in his study. We attribute the more “optimistic” findings from our analysis to the inclusion of internal trade values in our estimation. As shown in Dai et al. (2014), internal trade is an important component of the overall reference group for estimating theoretically consistent effects of trade policies; thus, estimations that include internal trade generally obtain larger, more precisely estimated FTA effects.32

Table 1. Estimates of agreement-specific FTA effects.

Agreement βA se. Agreement βA se. Agreement βA se.
Positive effects:     (cont’d)     (cont’d)    
Bulgaria-Turkey† 1.485 0.342 Israel-Mexico 0.553 0.136 Israel-Romania 0.174 0.195
EU-Romania† 1.463 0.142 EU-Turkey† 0.535 0.083 Pan Arab FTA 0.171 0.192
Romania-Turkey† 1.403 0.165 Canada-Costa Rica 0.492 0.189 EU-Egypt 0.149 0.125
Andean Community† 1.331 0.170 Canada-Israel† 0.481 0.091 Australia-Singapore 0.139 0.282
Israel-Turkey† 1.269 0.434 Egypt-Turkey 0.463 0.232 EU-Morocco 0.117 0.090
EU-Bulgaria† 1.248 0.225 Chile-China 0.462 0.167 Morocco-US 0.096 0.106
CEFTA† 1.240 0.242 Tunisia-Turkey 0.389 0.109 EU-Chile† 0.045 0.111
EU-Poland† 1.162 0.195 EU-Mexico 0.313 0.095 EU† −0.016 0.066
Costa Rica-Mexico 1.087 0.461 Chile-US 0.283 0.128 Mercosur-Bolivia 0.007 0.260
Mercosur† 1.024 0.205 EU-Tunisia 0.283 0.086 EFTA-Singapore −0.018 0.248
EU-Hungary† 0.996 0.170 Chile-South Korea 0.275 0.103 ASEAN† −0.107 0.145
Poland-Turkey† 0.976 0.152       EFTA-Mexico† −0.140 0.142
Bulgaria-Israel† 0.948 0.212 Insignificant effects (p > .05): EFTA-Israel† −0.213 0.129
EFTA-Hungary† 0.939 0.244 Jordan-US 0.954 0.684 Singapore-US −0.279 0.312
Hungary-Turkey† 0.932 0.132 Canada-Chile 0.851 0.447      
EFTA-Poland† 0.921 0.193 Hungary-Israel 0.757 0.400 Negative effects:    
EFTA-Romania† 0.890 0.230 Mexico-Uruguay 0.463 0.377 Australia-US† −0.170 0.064
Colombia-Mexico† 0.762 0.226 Chile-Costa Rica 0.419 0.313 EU-Cyprus† −0.194 0.096
EFTA-Bulgaria 0.740 0.353 EFTA-Morocco 0.384 0.234 EU-Israel† −0.256 0.080
Japan-Mexico† 0.701 0.115 Mercosur-Chile 0.353 0.244 Canada-US† −0.375 0.126
NAFTA† 0.662 0.152 EFTA-Turkey 0.299 0.154 Chile-Singapore† −1.099 0.174
Australia-Thailand† 0.623 0.093 EU-EFTA 0.294 0.184      
Mercosur-Andean† 0.622 0.125 Chile-Mexico 0.266 0.486      
Israel-Poland 0.566 0.202 Agadir Agreement 0.188 0.123      
Summary statistics
Simple   Weighted Averages  
Median βA estimate:: 0.0.463 by inverse variance 0.293
Mean βA estimate: 0.491 by number of country-pairs 0.382
Variance of estimates: 0.261 by (#pairs×inv. var): 0.200

This table reports estimates of the partial FTA effects for all agreements in our sample. Standard errors are “three-way” clustered by exporter, importer, and year. † denotes estimates that are statistically different from the overall average estimate of β = 0.293. There are 33 such estimates, or 50.8%. See text for further details.

Fig. 1

Fig. 1. Distribution of agreement-level FTA partial effects, with 95% CIs.

Second, we notice that some countries in our sample generally seem to have had consistently larger (partial equilibrium) impacts from trade agreements. Central and Eastern European countries in particular (e.g., Bulgaria, Hungary, Romania, Poland) are well-represented in the first column of Table 1. We also note generally strong effects for agreements signed by Israel, Turkey, Mexico, Mercosur, and the Andean Community. On the other hand, with the exception of Israel and Turkey, other Mediterranean nations – such as Egypt, Tunisia, and Morocco- have generally experienced more modest effects. We will return to this issue of whether some countries consistently experience larger FTA effects than others in our second stage analysis in Section 5.

Overall, the estimates from Table 1 and Fig. 1 confirm that FTAs have had very heterogeneous effects on trade. The degree of heterogeneity we document echoes some earlier findings in the literature, although we generally observe a more optimistic picture of the efficacy of FTAs on an agreement-by-agreement basis. While these factual considerations are useful to note, there remain three important avenues along which we would like to deepen the analysis. First, many agreements involve three or more countries; thus, we wish to examine how the same agreement will affect different pairs of member countries. Second, policymakers generally want to know how trade policies will affect their countries specifically; thus, it is important to allow for direction-specificFTA effects. Third, as noted in Baier et al. (2018), even the most finely-tuned appraisals of past FTAs do not by themselves tell us anything about what the effects of future FTAs will look like. These considerations motivate our more detailed pair- and direction-specificFTA estimates.

4.4. Pair-specific and direction-specific estimates

Given the number of estimates we can potentially obtain from specifications (7) and (8) – 455 and 910, respectively – it is not practical to present a full listing of the many pair- and direction-specific effects we estimate. Instead, we summarize the heterogeneity we observe in our pair- and direction-specific estimates in two complementary ways. First, in Table 2, we offer a snapshot of the substantial variation in partial effects that can be observed within a single agreement, using the E.U. as our example. Second, in Fig. 2 and Fig. 3, we add graphical depictions of how the distribution of partial effects changes when we allow for more specificity, i.e. for variation at the agreement-pair level and for directional effects at the agreement-pair level, respectively. The distributions shown in Fig. 2 can be compared directly with the distribution of agreement-specific effects shown in Fig. 1. The two plots shown in Fig. 3 then more specifically highlight, respectively, the degree of pair-wise heterogeneity within each agreement and the degree of asymmetry within each pair.

Table 2. Heterogeneity in EU accession effects.

Pair βEU:p se. Pair βEU:p se. Pair βEU:p se.
Largest EU accession effects (by pair):
Hungary-Poland*† 2.186 0.487 Cyprus-Hungary* 0.503 0.251 Spain-Poland 0.412 0.228
Cyprus-Finland*† 1.711 0.399 BLX-Cyprus* 0.493 0.176 U.K.-Hungary 0.400 0.218
Hungary-Malta*† 1.600 0.571 Finland-Hungary 0.470 0.418 Austria-BLX* 0.394 0.086
Austria-Malta* 1.101 0.514 U.K.-Poland* 0.469 0.225 Austria-Spain* 0.375 0.191
Cyprus-Netherlands*† 0.716 0.135 Cyprus-Greece* 0.457 0.196 Italy-Poland* 0.370 0.168
Cyprus-U.K. 0.703 0.370 Cyprus-Germany* 0.456 0.153 BLX-Finland* 0.352 0.100
Cyprus-Italy* 0.555 0.139 Denmark-Hungary* 0.437 0.149 Austria-Poland* 0.352 0.105
France-Poland* 0.517 0.147 BLX-Sweden* 0.431 0.129 Germany-Poland* 0.334 0.110
 
Small and negative EU accession effects (by pair):
Austria-Sweden† −0.202 0.107 Cyprus-Malta −0.307 0.371 Denmark-Finland*† −0.443 0.150
Germany-Malta† −0.205 0.112 Finland-Sweden*† −0.312 0.102 Cyprus-Denmark*† −0.455 0.213
Greece-Sweden† −0.210 0.255 Denmark-Malta† −0.327 0.193 Italy-Malta† −0.584 0.403
U.K.-Sweden† −0.213 0.143 Finland-U.K.*† −0.331 0.133 Finland-Portugal† −0.630 0.441
Germany-Sweden*† −0.220 0.107 Cyprus-Ireland*† −0.334 0.159 Portugal-Sweden*† −0.694 0.353
Finland-Italy† −0.256 0.136 Finland-Ireland*† −0.356 0.125 Ireland-Malta*† −1.069 0.232
Hungary-Ireland† −0.269 0.264 Italy-Sweden*† −0.360 0.087 Cyprus-Poland*† −1.220 0.247
Ireland-Sweden*† −0.291 0.144 BLX-Hungary† −0.399 0.210 Greece-Malta*† −1.819 0.308
Pair βEU:d se. Pair βEU:d se. Pair βEU:d se.
Examples of asymmetric EU accession effects (arrows indicate direction of trade):
Netherlands →Austria* 0.418 0.158 Spain →Austria*† 0.734 0.212 Poland →Austria* 0.575 0.186
Austria →Netherlands*† −0.486 0.162 Austria →Spain 0.110 0.187 Austria →Poland 0.157 0.152
Poland →Spain* 0.795 0.258 Poland →Sweden* 0.549 0.223 Poland →Netherlands 0.364 0.193
Spain →Poland 0.057 0.183 Sweden →Poland 0.040 0.156 Netherlands →Poland 0.157 0.158
Poland →U.K.*† 0.825 0.266 U.K. →Sweden 0.048 0.197 Sweden →Austria −0.105 0.224
U.K. →Poland 0.100 0.184 Sweden →U.K.*† −0.431 0.182 Austria →Sweden† −0.293 0.239
Netherlands →Sweden 0.317 0.199 Spain →Sweden 0.285 0.209 U.K. →Austria* 0.342 0.141
Sweden →Netherlands† −0.353 0.200 Sweden →Spain† −0.152 0.207 Austria →U.K. 0.197 0.147
Summary of within-EU estimates
Pairwise estimates (βEU:p) Directional estimates (βEU:d)
Mean: 0.047 Median: 0.046 s.d.: 0.514 Mean: 0.085 Median: 0.048 s.d.: 0574
# positive and significant: 27/98 (27.6%) # positive and significant: 37/196 (18.9%)
# negative and significant: 13/98 (13.3%) # negative and significant: 26/196 (13.3%)
# statistically different from β = 0.293: 41/98 (41.8%) # statistically different from β = 0.293: 82/196 (41.8%)

This table reports examples of pair-specific and asymmetric estimated partial effects for the EU accessions in our sample. * denotes estimates that are statistically different from 0. † denotes estimates that are statistically different from the overall average estimate of β = 0.293. See text for further details.

Fig. 2

Fig. 2. Distributions of agreement-pair-specific (left) and direction-specific (right) FTA effects, with 95% CIs.

Fig. 3

Fig. 3. Pair-wise heterogeneity within agreements (left); directional heterogeneity within Pairs (right).

We focus on the E.U. in Table 2 because it is by far the largest agreement in our sample. There are 98 distinct pair-specific effects -and 196 direction-specific effects – that can be estimated within the E.U. alone. Rather than show all these estimates, Table 2 presents (roughly) the upper and lower quartiles from the pair-specific effects, as well as some representative examples of asymmetries within pairs. Both panels of Fig. 3 also place these EU-specific estimates in the context of the heterogeneity we observe within other agreements, such as NAFTA and the E.U.’s agreements with Poland and Chile.

From the top panel of Table 2, we can clearly see a very wide variance in the effects of recent E.U. accessions across different E.U. pairs. Consistent with our expectation that more finely-grained estimates should exhibit relatively more noise, the ranking of the various estimates seems somewhat more random than the ordering seen in Table 1. Smaller countries, such as Malta and Cyprus, appear regularly at the extremes of both lists. Other, more economically large countries – such as the U.K., Hungary, and Portugal- also appear multiple times on both lists.

The lower panel of Table 2 shows some representative examples of E.U. pairs with strongly asymmetric E.U. pairs. For brevity, we only show these effects for three acceding countries (Poland, Austria, and Sweden) and three existing E.U. members (Netherlands, Spain, and the U.K.), though these examples are generally representative. Here, we do see strong, country-specific patterns, confirming again the general pattern suggested by Table 1. Poland’s accession has led more so to increases in exports from Poland to existing E.U. members than to increases in trade in the other direction. This dynamic does not appear to be a regular function of E.U. accession, however: asymmetries in the Spain-Austria and Netherlands-Austria pairs both favor trade flows to the acceding country (in these cases, Austria) rather than the other way around. We also see a similar pattern for Sweden, another acceding country, in its pairings with these countries. Overall, these examples suggest that, even within agreements, there can be large, country-specific patterns of effects that are worth investigating further.

The graphical depictions of the distributions of our various estimates from Fig. 2Fig. 3 echo these same messages and provide a broader overview.33 The wider confidence intervalsseen in each panel of Fig. 2 confirm that, as we move to increasingly more detailed estimates, it becomes increasingly more difficult to obtain statistical precision. Indeed, only 40.4% of our agreement-pair-specific estimates (shown in the left panel of Fig. 2) are positive and statistically significant, with this same percentage narrowing to 32.0% for our direction-specific estimates (shown in the right panel of Fig. 2). Fig. 3 then uses different colors to separate out these effects by the different agreements they belong to. The left panel of Fig. 3, which plots agreement-specific estimates against pair-specific estimates, confirms there is generally substantial heterogeneity within the same agreement whenever multiple pairs are involved. Finally, the right panel of Fig. 3, which plots directional effects within the same pair against one another, then shows that asymmetries within pairs are also very prevalent, but – at the same time – directional FTAeffects within the same pair tend to be highly correlated with one another.

Admittedly, as we focus on increasingly specific estimates of changes in trade costs associated with FTAs, we also increase the likelihood that our estimates reflect omitted factors that may enter specifications (6)–(8) via the error term. Causal interpretation of these more specific FTA effects would require that these effects are directly reflected in changes in trade that occur around the time of the agreement. While this assumption may not strictly hold in all (or even most) cases, presenting these results still allows for a broad description of the vast heterogeneity we observe in the ex post partial effects of FTAs in our sample, especially within agreements. In addition, while we acknowledge that individual FTA effects may be measured with unobservable error, taken collectively, these effects can still be analyzed to determine what factors may be expected to be associated with stronger or weaker effects ex ante. This is the focus of our second stage analysis.

5. On the determinants of the effects of FTAs

In this section, we capitalize on the rich database of FTA estimates that we have constructed in order to study their determinants. We start with a description of our econometric approach and a general characterization of the heterogeneity we observe in our first stage FTA estimates. We then launch into a “second stage” analysis, which takes the direction-agreement-specific partial effects from our estimation of (8) as our dependent variable and regresses them on various covariates of interest in order to gauge and decompose the determinants of these effects. As part of this analysis, we introduce two new variables that prove to be important determinants of the effects of FTAs: (i) our comprehensive index of “pre-FTA trade barriers”, which we hope to use to explain the overall magnitude of FTA partial effects, and (ii) our index of “revealed market power”, which we will use to investigate potential asymmetries in FTA effects as well as to test some prominent theoretical predictions drawn from Bagwell & Staiger (1999). Importantly, our two stage design makes it easy for us to test how these and other variables contribute to heterogeneous effects within the same agreement and/or within the same pair. The insights that we obtain in this section will feed into the out-of-sample and ex ante prediction analysis that will follow in Section 6.

5.1. Econometric approach

Before turning to the full-blown second stage analysis, we pause to consider two preliminary matters of interest. First, because our first stage estimates of FTA partial effects have been potentially estimated with unobservable error, it is important to discuss how this this error enters the second stage and how our analysis may be structured to account for it. An exceptionally useful reference in this regard is Lewis & Linzer (2005), who carefully examine the consequences of various different ways of weighting a “second stage” dependent variable to account for residual error variance from a prior stage. As Lewis & Linzer (2005)demonstrate, so long as a White (1980) correction for heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors is used, simply using (unweighted) OLS to estimate the second stage will enable us to obtain conservative, if inefficient, inferences of our second stage parameters. That is, while other weighting methods might lead to more efficient estimates, the White (1980) correction should still generate reliable consistent estimates of our second stage standard errors and confidence intervals, such that we should not be worried about “over-confidence” in our inferences. Lewis & Linzer (2005) also demonstrate that other popular weighting methods for dealing with first stage error can actually perform far worse in terms of efficiency and generally conclude that OLS with heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors is “probably the best approach” in most cases. With these recommendations in mind, we adhere strictly to OLS with robust standard errors for all of our main second stage regressions.34

Second, as a direct lead-in for the second stage, we perform a standard “analysis of variance” exercise, sequentially adding agreement-specific followed by (symmetric) pair-agreement-specific dummy variables as regressors in order to absorb all variance that is associated with heterogeneity “across agreements” and (respectively) “across pairs within agreements”. The remaining variance, that is not specific to either an agreement or a pair within agreement, then strictly reflects residual asymmetries in estimated FTA effects within pairs of countries. The main results from this initial decomposition exercise are as follows. First, the agreement-level dummies we use to absorb differences across agreements collectively only explain 35.5% of the overall variation in our estimated directional FTA effects (measured by R2). When we parse the estimates further by next adding pair-agreement-level dummies, the share of explained variation increases to 70.4%, suggesting that 70.4 %  − 35.5 %  = 34.9% can be explained by heterogeneity across different pairs within the same agreement. The remaining unexplained variation, 29.6%, specifically reflects asymmetries within the same pair. Notably, this last term is of comparable magnitude to the other two components.

Usefully, this exercise also serves to preview some of the techniques we will use in the analysis that follows to isolate how different variables may explain different aspects of the overall heterogeneity in our estimates. For example, regressing our FTA estimates on a set of observables in the presence of agreement-level fixed effects will allow us to narrowly focus on potential sources of “within agreement” heterogeneity. Similarly, the introduction of agreement-by-pair fixed effects will, much as in our initial decomposition exercise, allow us to narrow the focus further to sources of “asymmetries within pairs”. Generally speaking, heterogeneity in FTA partial effects within agreements is a topic which has not received much attention in the literature, despite its intuitive appeal. The opportunity to selectively vary our focus in this way – made significantly easier by approaching the problem in two stages – will thus be a key aspect of our overall methodology.

5.2. Decomposing the sources of FTA heterogeneity

The preceding discussion highlighted broad patterns of heterogeneity in our first stage FTA estimates. In earlier sections, we have also described at length some attractive, theoretically-guided indices for potentially accounting for some of this variance. The stage is set for a more detailed investigation: What can we say about the empirical determinants of FTA effects? In short order, we will introduce a wide variety of covariates that may hold sway in this context, including “economic geography” variables, institutional factors, as well as neoclassical determinants of trade. For now, however, we start with only a basic specification, drawing solely on a few key hypotheses:

(14)βA:d=α0+α1lnFirststagepairFEij+α2lnToT^A:j+α3Ext.Marginij,t−1+νij.

As we have established in Section 3.2, each of the key variables in (14) has an intuitive expected sign. The first stage pair fixed effect term, for example, provides a novel and comprehensive (inverse) measure of the level of trade frictions between i and j just before the signing of their agreement. Intuitively, country-pairs with a lower first stage pair fixed effect suffer from higher ex ante bilateral trade frictions and, therefore, have more potential for larger trade creation effects from FTAs ex post.35 We therefore expect the sign of α1 to be negative. lnToT^A:j, meanwhile, measures the sensitivity of the importer’s terms of tradebased on the simulation procedure described in Section 3.2. A smaller lnToT^A:j indicates that the importing country has relatively more influence over the terms of trade over its partners. Thus, we expect that α2 < 0, in accordance with the influential arguments of Bagwell & Staiger (1999). We also expect that α3, the coefficient on the ex ante extensive margin, to be < 0, incorporating the arguments of Kehoe & Ruhl (2013).

Column 1 of Table 3 shows the results from this simple specification testing each of the above hypotheses. The first stage pair fixed effect andlnToT^A:j, enter with the expected sign and are highly statistically significant (with p-values less than 0.01). Interestingly, the coefficient for our extensive margin measure is significant and positive: conditional on our other covariates, countries which trade a wider range of products with one another ex anteexperience stronger trade creation effects from FTAs ex post, contrary to the earlier findings by Kehoe & Ruhl (2013) and Kehoe et al. (2015). We offer an explanation for this finding below, where we more specifically study the heterogeneity in our FTA estimates that is due to asymmetries within pairs.

Table 3. Second Stage Estimates: Baseline.

  Dependent variable: First stage directional FTA estimates
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
First stage pair FE† −0.195*** −0.372*** −0.261***   −0.154*** −0.346*** −0.246***  
(0.034) (0.041) (0.057)   (0.036) (0.041) (0.056)  
lnToT^A:j −17.424*** −10.786*** −7.616** −9.423*** −19.392*** −13.557*** −5.881* −7.978**
(2.483) (2.995) (3.193) (3.284) (2.871) (3.120) (3.245) (3.241)
Extensive margin of trade 1.167*** 0.555** 0.349 −0.573* 0.932*** 0.402 0.249 −0.697**
(0.170) (0.263) (0.246) (0.303) (0.174) (0.268) (0.253) (0.334)
Count Enf. Provisions         0.484* 0.242    
        (0.256) (0.324)    
Institutional Quality         0.493* 0.631*    
        (0.296) (0.328)    
Customs Union         0.005 0.053    
        (0.087) (0.073)    
ln 1 + AppliedTariff         1.200** −0.228 −0.736 −1.008
        (0.529) (0.572) (0.710) (0.647)
ln DIST   −0.456*** −0.241***     −0.474*** −0.257***  
  (0.044) (0.081)     (0.057) (0.085)  
CONTIG   0.188** −0.003     0.144 −0.044  
  (0.093) (0.103)     (0.104) (0.104)  
COLONY   0.014 0.076     −0.050 0.120  
  (0.100) (0.111)     (0.102) (0.115)  
LANG   0.112 0.073     0.264*** 0.032  
  (0.082) (0.093)     (0.091) (0.098)  
LEGAL   0.161** 0.262***     0.190** 0.248***  
  (0.075) (0.080)     (0.076) (0.080)  
Prior Agreement   −0.262*** −0.000     −0.235*** 0.028  
  (0.055) (0.085)     (0.072) (0.086)  
Exporter (log) Real GDP   0.202*** 0.152***     0.205*** 0.169***  
  (0.035) (0.038)     (0.037) (0.040)  
Importer (log) Real GDP   0.146*** 0.091*** −0.139***   0.111*** 0.069** −0.182***
  (0.026) (0.030) (0.043)   (0.028) (0.030) (0.048)
Exporter (log) GDP per capita   −0.067 0.002     −0.059 0.071  
  (0.083) (0.108)     (0.099) (0.136)  
Importer (log) GDP per capita   0.172*** 0.235*** 0.117   0.145** 0.271** 0.071
  (0.048) (0.086) (0.079)   (0.070) (0.116) (0.098)
Constant 0.349*** 0.349***     0.349*** 0.363***    
(0.029) (0.026)     (0.032) (0.028)    
Agreement FEs     x       x  
Agr.×pair FEs       x       x
Observations 908 908 908 908 826 826 852 806
R2 0.078 0.261 0.424 0.729 0.099 0.270 0.427 0.740
Within R2     0.107 0.086     0.104 0.118

This table reports second stage OLS estimates with robust standard errors (reported in parentheses). The dependent variable is βA:d, an estimated direction-specific FTA partial effect which we have estimated in a priorstage. Observation counts vary in columns 5–8 versus columns 1–4 because of the limited availability of tariff data (from TRAINS) and information on the number of enforceable provisions and institutional quality for each FTA (from Kohl et al., 2016). In columns 1, 2, 4, and 5, all variables are de-meaned with respect to their within-sample mean. This allows us to interpret the regression constant as reflecting the overall average FTA estimate after netting out the average effects of each of the included covariates. *p < 0.10, ** p < .05, *** p < .01. † Also accounts for “globalization” effects. See text for further details.

Column 2 adds several other, more standard variables that specifically draw on the “gravity” literature. These include bilateral relationships – such as log distance, contiguity, the sharing of a common language, or the presence of a prior free trade agreement – and also the GDPs and GDP per capitas of each partner.36 For the most part, we do not impose strong priors on these added variables. We do, however, generally expect log distance (“  ln  DIST ”) to be negative, either because more distant countries are more sensitive to changes in trade policies (as emphasized in Baier et al. 2018) or perhaps because they simply sign weaker agreements due to weaker cultural affinities.37 Likewise, countries that already have a prior trade agreement (“ Prior Agreement ”) should experience weaker trade creation, because the earlier agreements have likely already picked much of the “low hanging fruit” in terms of easily addressed barriers to trade.

The signs on   ln  DIST  and  Prior Agreement  are indeed negative as expected. We also find larger FTA effects for contiguous countries (“CONTIG”) and for countries with common legal system (“LEGAL”). The positive and significant result we observe for CONTIG may be due to the same reasons we have already cited for the negative sign we observe on log distance. The positive and significant sign for LEGAL, however, merits further discussion, as we would ordinarily expect countries with dissimilar legal systems to have higher ex antebarriers to trade. The key remark to make here is that, because we already have in place an “inclusive” measure of trade costs – in the form of our first stage pair fixed effect – we may interpret these latter variables as affecting the efficacy of the FTAindependently of how they affect initial trade costs. Conditional on the level of ex ante trade frictions, sharing a common legal system (for example) could conceivably make it easier for countries to coordinate on stronger trade creation measures.

Three of the added country-level gravity variables— the log GDPs of both countries and the log per capita GDP of the importer— also enter the analysis significantly. Interestingly, we find that FTA effects are generally stronger for larger countries (measured in real GDP), both on the export-side as well as on the import-side, with the exporter’s GDP having more overall influence. While agreements between larger countries are associated with more trade, the combined impact is less than proportionate; that is, a 1% increase in export and importer GDP increases trade by less than 1%. The positive sign on the importer’s per capita GDP implies an asymmetry in how FTAs affect trade between countries with differing levels of development, a result we will query in more detail below.

Another important aspect of including a direct measure of country “size” in our analysis is that, all else equal, we would expect size/GDP to be a reasonable proxy for a country’s market power over world prices. However, while the magnitude of the coefficient for lnToT^A:j does weaken when we add these controls, it remains robustly significant. Furthermore, the relative magnitudes of the coefficients for GDPs are not consistent with a story based on market power: if anything, they suggest FTAs promote trade from larger countries to smaller ones. We also note that, while our estimate of the coefficient on the extensive margin variable is still positive and significant, its magnitude falls by roughly half when these other controls are added.

5.2.1. Within-agreement heterogeneity

As noted above, a unique aspect of our two stage design is that we can easily switch our focus from analyzing broad patterns of heterogeneity (as in Table 3) to the heterogeneity that occurs more narrowly within individual agreements and (later) within individual trading pairs. In addition, this approach will enable us to test the robustness of our results in the presence of a rich set of fixed effects. Column 3 of Table 3 repeats the same specification used in column 2, only now with added agreement-level fixed effects, such that our estimates now reflect only the residual variation that takes place within agreements. Most of our results carry over from before, with a few notable exceptions. For example, Prior Agreement now becomes very close to zero and statistically insignificant. Apparently, these limits are only relevant for determining the overall impact of an agreement on all partners; conditional on a multilateral agreement being signed (where at least one pair already has an agreement and one does not), we cannot identify an effect. CONTIG likewise loses its significance. Interestingly, our earlier, surprising result for the extensive margin also disappears when add agreement fixed effects.

5.2.2. Within-pair heterogeneity

To narrow the analysis even further, Column 4 of Table 3 moves from including agreement-level fixed effects (as in column 3) to now including (symmetric) agreement-by-pair fixed effects. Because these fixed effects absorb all symmetric bilateral variables (e.g., ln DIST, etc.), there are only a few key variables that can be identified, and their estimates should be interpreted carefully as strictly reflecting determinants of asymmetric FTA effects within pairs. For example, once again, we obtain a negative and highly significant estimate on lnToT^A:j. Because our agreement-pair fixed effects absorb the average level of trade liberalizationwithin every pair of FTA-signing countries, this result specifically indicates that asymmetries in trade barrier reductions strongly favor the exports of the country with relatively less market power. This to us is the most literal test of the “terms of trade” argument of Bagwell & Staiger (1999).

Turning to the other results in column 4, we once again confirm the exporter’s economic size (i.e., its log real GDP) is relatively more important than that of the importer. However, we are not able to confirm our finding from the previous specifications that asymmetries in FTA effects favor the exports of the less developed country (in per capita GDP terms). In addition, we note that the estimate on the extensive margin is now entering negatively, albeit with marginal statistical significance (p < 0.10). While this is still not strong evidence in favor of the “least traded goods” hypothesis, the comparison across specifications helps clarify why our earlier results differ starkly from Kehoe & Ruhl (2013) and Kehoe et al. (2015), since these studies each examine changes in trade within individual FTA pairings on a case-by-case basis, which is most similar to our focus on within-pair heterogeneity in column 4.

5.3. Robustness

Having established our main specifications in columns 1–4 of Table 3, we now move on to several key sensitivity analyses encompassing some natural lines of inquiry as well as some deeper concerns about causal interpretation. Our first task is to introduce more detailed information on trade policies in place and/or the “depth” of the agreement being signed. To this end, columns 5 to 8 of Table 3 repeat the same specifications as before, only now adding the pre-FTA tariff level (“ln 1 + AppliedTariff”, which uses weighted-average applied tariffs taken from TRAINS), a 0/1 dummy variable for if the agreement entails the formation of a customs union and/or common market, and two other, more specific measures of FTA depth (the “Count of Enforceable Provisions” and the “Institutional Quality” of the agreement, which we take from Kohl et al., 2016).38

The inclusion of these trade policy variables at first appears meaningful. In particular, the estimate on the ex ante tariff level in column 5, where we are repeating the same specification as column 1, is positive and highly significant as expected (p < .01). In addition, while the coefficient for Customs Union is basically zero, the other depth measures also enter positively, albeit with marginal (p < .10) significance.39 Interestingly, the statistical significance of ln Appliedtariff disappears in the presence of gravity controls (column 6), agreement fixed effects (column 7), or agreement-pair fixed effects (column 8). Our original main variables and controls, meanwhile, remain largely unaffected. We conclude, based on these results, that our approach allows us to capture important sources of variation in the ex post effects of FTAs that go beyond what we can infer based on tariffs alone.40

Next, we consider two further sets of variables that may plausibly be linked to larger FTA effects: (i) “institutional” factors (such as each country’s rule of law, the degree of democracy, etc.) and (ii) the role of factor endowment differences and other “Neoclassically” motivated drivers of trade creation. Columns 1–4 of Table 4 investigate the role played by institutions. The institutional indicators we consider are: each country’s rule of law and bureaucracy quality (each from the Institutional Country Risk Guide), their degree of democracy (from Polity IV), and the degree of “checks and balances” in their respective political systems (from the World Bank’s Database of Political Institutions). For some motivation, we are interested to know whether asymmetries in FTA effects tend to favor the exports of countries with low levels of institutional development levels, based on the supposition that FTAs may help developing countries circumvent constraints on their export capacity imposed by their weak institutional environment (c.f., Anderson & Marcouiller, 2002Manova, 2013). Additionally, the political science literature (c.f., Mansfield et al., 2007) has argued that stronger checksand balances and/or a stronger degree of democracy should weaken the ability of an executive to enact more sweeping trade policy changes.

Table 4. Second Stage Estimates: Institutions and Factor Endowments.

  Dependent variable: First stage directional FTA estimates
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
First stage pair FE† −0.160*** −0.296*** −0.263***   −0.156*** −0.257*** −0.233***  
(0.038) (0.047) (0.072)   (0.036) (0.042) (0.060)  
lnToT^A:j −17.127*** −12.921*** −8.662*** −9.347*** −5.373** −5.988** −6.404** −7.939***
(3.175) (3.186) (3.297) (3.547) (2.530) (2.640) (2.974) (2.805)
Extensive margin of trade 1.383*** 0.725** 0.252 −0.362 1.103*** 0.268 0.301 −0.253
(0.182) (0.281) (0.274) (0.346) (0.185) (0.266) (0.282) (0.315)
Exporter Democracy 0.046*** 0.054*** 0.055          
(0.015) (0.015) (0.035)          
Importer Democracy 0.050*** 0.049*** 0.049 −0.007        
(0.012) (0.012) (0.032) (0.019)        
Exporter Bureaucracy Quality −0.459*** −0.261*** −0.023          
(0.045) (0.056) (0.067)          
Importer Bureaucracy Quality −0.268*** −0.170*** 0.060 0.074        
(0.044) (0.062) (0.070) (0.064)        
Exporter Checks and Balances 0.057*** 0.045*** 0.020          
(0.018) (0.017) (0.018)          
Importer Checks and Balances 0.038** 0.016 0.001 −0.018        
(0.019) (0.018) (0.019) (0.019)        
Exporter Rule of Law 0.089*** 0.060** −0.019          
(0.027) (0.029) (0.042)          
Importer Rule of Law 0.191*** 0.139*** 0.058 0.066        
(0.030) (0.029) (0.044) (0.040)        
Exp. (log) Physical Capital / Labor ratio         −0.461*** −0.260*** −0.082  
        (0.054) (0.088) (0.152)  
Imp. (log) Physical Capital / Labor ratio         −0.188*** −0.151 0.027 0.088
        (0.050) (0.098) (0.140) (0.106)
Exp. (log) Human Capital / Labor ratio         0.423* 0.228 0.240  
        (0.235) (0.250) (0.282)  
Imp. (log) Human Capital / Labor ratio         0.908*** 0.525** 0.547* 0.313
        (0.241) (0.250) (0.308) (0.246)
|Δ (log) Physical Capital / Labor ratio |         0.419*** 0.175** −0.205  
        (0.073) (0.075) (0.141)  
|Δ (log) Human Capital / Labor ratio |         0.424* 0.064 −0.188  
        (0.240) (0.244) (0.366)  
|Δ (log) GDP per capita |         −0.429*** −0.125 0.334  
        (0.098) (0.100) (0.206)  
Constant 0.351*** 0.325***     0.321*** 0.415***    
(0.028) (0.029)     (0.034) (0.044)    
Gravity controls   x x x   x x x
Agreement FEs     x       x  
Agr.×pair FEs       x       x
Observations 826 826 826 826 716 716 716 716
R2 0.268 0.349 0.472 0.733 0.332 0.416 0.502 0.774
Within R2     0.139 0.095     0.152 0.132

This table reports second stage OLS estimates with robust standard errors (reported in parentheses). The dependent variable is βA:d, an estimated direction-specific FTA partial effect which we have estimated in a priorstage. Observation counts vary due to the limited availability of factor endowment information (from PWT 9.0) and data on country institutions (from ICRG). In columns 1, 2, 4, and 5, all variables are de-meaned with respect to their within-sample mean. This allows us to interpret the regression constant as reflecting the overall average FTA estimate after netting out the average effects of each of the included covariates. “Gravity variables” (suppressed for brevity) include ln DIST, CONTIG, COLONY, LANG, LEGAL, Prior Agreement, GDPs, and per capita GDPs. Full results available on request. * p < 0.10, ** p < .05, *** p < .01. † Also accounts for “globalization” effects. See text for further details.

The results of these experiments offer mixed support for the notion that FTAs specifically promote the exports of countries with weak institutions. When we look at broad results without any agreement-level or agreement-pair fixed effects (columns 1 and 2 of Table 4), we generally find that FTAs have stronger effects for countries with strong legal institutions (i.e., high “Rule of Law”) and/or weak bureaucratic institutions (i.e., low “Bureaucracy Quality”). While there is indeed an implied asymmetry potentially favoring exporters with weaker institutions in these initial specifications, all of these variables lose their significance when we introduce agreement fixed effects (in column 3) as well as when we add agreement-pair fixed effects (in column 4). For democracy and checks and balances, we see a similar story: in columns 1 and 2, we overwhelmingly find that these variables are positively associated with signing stronger agreements. However, they play no role in explaining heterogeneity within agreements. Other key results remain unchanged.

Motivated by the Neoclassical “Heckscher-Ohlin” trade theory, the remaining columns of Table 4 control for factor endowment differences across countries (e.g., physical and human capital-to-labor ratios, skill-to-labor ratios). We also include the absolute difference in these relative endowments, as well as the absolute difference in (log) per capita GDPs, in order to get at various potential dimensions of comparative advantage. Data for each of these endowment measures are constructed using information from the Penn World Table. Echoing what we have seen in previous results, while we do find some significant results of note – in particular for physical capital-ratios and the difference therein – these results only appear to be meaningful for describing variations in FTA effects across different agreements. When we examine these variables in the presence of agreement fixed effects (column 7) or agreement-pair fixed effects (column 8), none are robustly significant. Our main results still retain the same sign and significance.

Finally, as we have discussed, the identification of our second stage covariates requires that the unobservable “noise” present in our first stage estimates can be treated as part of the second stage error term. To devise a practical falsification test for this assumption, we utilize what we will call the “first stage residual” from the years leading up to each agreement, defined as

lnresidt0−m=lnXij,t0−m/X^ij,t0−m,

where “Xijt0−m” is the volume of trade sent from i to j in year t0 − m before an agreement beginning in year t0 and “X^ij,t0−m” is its fitted value from (8). In principle, by including these residuals directly in the second stage, as we do in Table 5, we can verify to what extent our first stage estimates are picking up pre-existing changes in trade patterns as well as whether these pre-existing changes affect the identification of our second stage estimates. In practice, since earlier work by Magee (2008) has shown that a substantial portion of trade creation occurs in the 4 years leading up to an FTA- an “anticipation effect” – we look to see if we can draw a reasonable line between where we would expect to see only noise versus where we might expect to see anticipation when we add these residuals to our second stage.

Table 5. Second Stage Estimates: Anticipation Effects.

  Dependent variable: First stage directional FTA estimates
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
First stage pair FE † −0.350*** −0.280*** −0.289*** −0.224*** −0.221*** −0.234***      
(0.035) (0.032) (0.030) (0.047) (0.044) (0.039)      
lnToT^A:j −11.286*** −9.082*** −8.989*** −7.525** −5.769** −5.745** −9.586*** −6.894*** −6.940***
(2.983) (2.478) (2.471) (3.288) (2.680) (2.709) (3.387) (2.560) (2.609)
Extensive margin of trade 0.491** 0.347* 0.365* 0.248 0.152 0.179 −0.618** −0.460* −0.457*
(0.248) (0.208) (0.201) (0.242) (0.212) (0.214) (0.294) (0.247) (0.249)
ln DIST −0.451*** −0.316*** −0.317*** −0.246*** −0.250*** −0.248***      
(0.044) (0.036) (0.036) (0.081) (0.080) (0.079)      
CONTIG 0.191** 0.105 0.126* −0.046 −0.056 −0.033      
(0.097) (0.074) (0.077) (0.105) (0.090) (0.090)      
COLONY 0.021 −0.024 −0.028 0.102 0.154 0.161      
(0.103) (0.085) (0.085) (0.111) (0.110) (0.108)      
LANG 0.097 0.054 0.065 0.041 −0.053 −0.052      
(0.085) (0.071) (0.071) (0.094) (0.088) (0.085)      
LEGAL 0.147** 0.136** 0.131** 0.245*** 0.209*** 0.207***      
(0.072) (0.061) (0.059) (0.079) (0.070) (0.069)      
Prior Agreement −0.291*** −0.207*** −0.222*** 0.005 −0.008 −0.020      
(0.060) (0.049) (0.052) (0.083) (0.072) (0.071)      
Exporter (log) Real GDP 0.212*** 0.112*** 0.110*** 0.164*** 0.093*** 0.088***      
(0.036) (0.027) (0.027) (0.039) (0.032) (0.032)      
Importer (log) Real GDP 0.124*** 0.083*** 0.086*** 0.071** 0.055** 0.057** −0.172*** −0.086*** −0.087***
(0.026) (0.022) (0.022) (0.029) (0.025) (0.024) (0.043) (0.032) (0.032)
Exporter (log) GDP per capita −0.060 −0.025 −0.027 −0.030 0.033 0.037      
(0.082) (0.059) (0.053) (0.106) (0.094) (0.090)      
Importer (log) GDP per capita 0.193*** 0.158*** 0.157*** 0.214** 0.217*** 0.221*** 0.138* 0.102* 0.103*
(0.048) (0.036) (0.035) (0.086) (0.076) (0.074) (0.079) (0.060) (0.060)
ln residt0−6 −0.007   0.082 −0.007   0.077 −0.095   −0.023
(0.087)   (0.066) (0.087)   (0.069) (0.120)   (0.114)
ln residt0−5 0.074   0.046 0.127   0.086 0.068   0.001
(0.164)   (0.098) (0.161)   (0.099) (0.203)   (0.149)
ln residt0−4 0.024   −0.156 −0.017   −0.125 −0.019   0.010
(0.166)   (0.126) (0.163)   (0.124) (0.197)   (0.151)
ln residt0−3   0.165** 0.227***   0.147** 0.185**   0.103 0.095
  (0.068) (0.073)   (0.065) (0.073)   (0.099) (0.131)
ln residt0−2   0.267*** 0.269***   0.259*** 0.262***   0.262** 0.263***
  (0.082) (0.085)   (0.082) (0.085)   (0.104) (0.097)
ln residt0−1   0.654*** 0.642***   0.584*** 0.577***   0.656*** 0.658***
  (0.103) (0.098)   (0.108) (0.100)   (0.118) (0.105)
Constant 0.355*** 0.356*** 0.356***            
(0.027) (0.022) (0.022)            
Agreement FEs   x     x     x  
Agr.×pair FEs     x     x     x
Observations 874 876 874 874 876 874 874 876 874
R2 0.262 0.508 0.515 0.433 0.606 0.612 0.742 0.824 0.824
Within R2       0.114 0.385 0.394 0.119 0.399 0.399

This table reports second stage OLS estimates with robust standard errors (in parentheses). “ln residt0−m” is defined as lnXij,t0−m/X^ij,t0−m, where “Xijt0−m” is the volume of trade sent from i to j in the year t0 − m leading up to an agreement which begins in year t0 and “X^ij,t0−m” is its fitted value from the first stage estimation. Observation counts vary because we do not observe these residuals for the earliest agreements in the sample. In columns 1–3, all variables are de-meaned with respect to their within-sample mean. This allows us to interpret the regression constant as reflecting the overall average FTA estimate after netting out the average effects of each of the included covariates. * p < 0.10, ** p < .05, *** p < .01. † Also accounts for “globalization” effects. See text for further details.

The estimates from Table 5 show that such a line clearly exists between the 3rd and 4th year leading up to an FTA: when we include residuals from years t0 − 6 to t0 − 4 directly in our second stage, we observe no statistical relationship with our first stage estimates across all of our key specifications, whereas residuals from the two-to-three year period immediately preceding FTAs tend to be significantly correlated. Importantly, all our earlier results maintain the same signs and significance as in columns 2, 3, and 4 of Table 3 and their magnitudes are only modestly affected. Since we are now allowing actual changes in trade from just before an FTA to explain our estimates, this last set of results confirms that our second stage coefficients are primarily being identified by the trade growth that occurs after each FTA goes into effect.41

6. Out-of-sample predictions & ex ante analysis

In this section, we develop a simple, parsimonious prediction model for the effects of FTAs, using candidate predictors drawn from the main empirical results above. We then apply our model to the task of predicting the effects of a hypothetical U.S./E.U. FTA (“TTIP”) on the trade volumes and welfare of each all potential TTIP members and non-members in our sample. Notably, we find very large differences in predictions depending on whether we apply an average effect for TTIP versus specific predictions for TTIP’s effects on all possible trade flows between members.

6.1. Developing a prediction model

Our out-of-sample analysis proceeds by dropping one agreement at a time and then trying to predict its effects based on a model fitted using the other agreements in the sample. For our criteria, we aimed for a set of predictors which: (i) performs well against other alternatives in terms of R2; (ii) can be naturally motivated based on our empirical results from Section 5; (iii) contains variables that were shown to be important for “within-agreement” and (if applicable) “within-pair” heterogeneity. We also focus only on the 5th through 95th percentiles of our estimates.42

Based on these criteria, our preferred model is the following simple prediction specification:

(15)β˜A:d=α˜0+α˜1lnDISTij+α˜2FirststagepairFEij+α˜3GDPi+α˜4GDPj+α˜7lnToT^A:j+νij.

All the predictors used in (15) were shown to be consistently significant throughout the preceding section, especially when we zeroed in on heterogeneity within agreements and (if applicable) within pairs. FTA effects should be smaller for countries that have a higher first stage pair fixed effect (indicating lower ex ante trade frictions) and/or are further apart geographically, and/or if they already have an existing agreement in place. In addition, we also allow for asymmetries in FTA effects within pairs by including the GDPs of both partners and our (inverse) measure of the importing country’s market powerlnToT^A:jFig. 4 offers a visualization of the resulting predictive fit. Each data point in Fig. 4 represents a predicted FTA effect (indexed by the horizontal axis), which we compare with the actual estimate obtained from the first stage (indexed by the vertical axis). The coefficient on our fitted regression line, ρ1 = 0.773, is positive and highly significant. The constant from the fitted regression line, ρ0 = 0.091, is also positive and highly significant.

Fig. 4

Fig. 4. Out-of-sample validation results.

Before turning to TTIP, we acknowledge two limitations of this approach. First, the predictive fit of our preferred model (R2 = 0.178) indicates that we are able to predict a significant but modest amount of the overall heterogeneity in the effects of FTAs with our simple model. Obviously, if the R2 were our sole criterion, we could easily inflate the fit of our predictive model by adding many more variables on the righthand-side. However, this runs the risk of “overfitting” the model and, furthermore, leads us away from being able to provide an intuitive understanding of what factors are driving our predictions.43A second caveat is that, because not all the directional FTA effects we computed in our first stage are positive, our methodology can and will predict negative partial effects for at least some TTIP pairs. We do not take a stand on why we observe negative FTA effects in our estimates. Our prior would ordinarily be that TTIP should generally lead to trade creation between all pairs. Where negative values are encountered, we take this to mean that trade creation is likely to be small. Despite these limitations, we believe that our approach is able to shed light on some novel and meaningful sources of predictive power.

6.2. Predicting the effects of TTIP

Our task in this section is to predict the effects of a U.S./E.U. FTA, given different assumptions about how it will affect trade barriers between the U.S. and its prospective partners in the E.U. In particular, we will explore two main scenarios. Under the “average” scenario, we base the change in trade barriers for all U.S./E.U. pairs on our estimate of the overall average partial effect using (5). In other words, τ^ij−θ=eβavg=e0.293, for all U.S./E.U. pairs. Under our second, “heterogeneous” scenario, we predict direction-pair-specific partial effects for TTIP using the insights from our prior analysis. In particular, we let τ^ij−θ=eβij,where βij is computed using both the coefficients estimated from our preferred second stage model as well as the ρ’s shown in Fig. 4. In other words,

(16)βij=0.091+0.773⋅β˜TTIP:d,

where β˜TTIP:d is the fitted value for each directional pair d within TTIP computed from our second stage estimates. Essentially, we are using the predictive fit from our out-of-sample validation analysis to determine how much weight we should place on our ability to predict heterogeneity in partial effects (ρ1 = 0.773), versus using a common average component (ρ0 = 0.091). We use this information in the interest of providing additional conservatism. The underlying regression coefficients used to compute β˜TTIP:d are:

(17)β˜TTIP:d=2.909−0.311⋅lnDISTij−0.221⋅FirststagepairFEij+0.145⋅lnGDPi+0.114⋅lnGDPj−10.861⋅lnToT^A:j,

which are computed using all agreements in the sample, instead of excluding one at a time. All estimates shown in (17) are statistically different from zero at the p < 0.01 significance level.

The predicted partial effects for TTIP are shown in Table 6, along with their standard errors. Notably, they are highly heterogeneous. The overall mean— 0.256 if weighted by trade, 0.302 if not— is in the same ballpark as the overall average partial effect we estimated from the data (0.293). Consistent with what we saw previously with E.U. accession effects, the largest partial effects, in excess of 0.400 in each direction, involve the Eastern European E.U. members Bulgaria, Romania, and Poland (with fellow Eastern European member Hungary not far behind). The smallest values involve U.S. trade with both Ireland and Malta.

Table 6. Predicting the Partial Effects of TTIP.

Exporter Importer βTTIP:d Exporter Importer βTTIP:d
Predicted partial effects of TTIP (by TTIP pair)
United States Austria 0.319 (0.220, 0.417) Austria United States 0.219 (0.126, 0.313)
United States Belgium-Lux. 0.249 (0.147, 0.350) Belgium-Lux. United States 0.147 (0.055, 0.239)
United States Bulgaria 0.536 (0.428, 0.645) Bulgaria United States 0.397 (0.284, 0.510)
United States Cyprus 0.399 (0.277, 0.522) Cyprus United States 0.218 (0.088, 0.348)
United States Denmark 0.315 (0.216, 0.414) Denmark United States 0.207 (0.113, 0.300)
United States Finland 0.335 (0.235, 0.435) Finland United States 0.218 (0.123, 0.313)
United States France 0.346 (0.245, 0.448) France United States 0.290 (0.195, 0.386)
United States Germany 0.305 (0.201, 0.410) Germany United States 0.264 (0.165, 0.364)
United States Greece 0.467 (0.365, 0.569) Greece United States 0.352 (0.252, 0.452)
United States Hungary 0.399 (0.298, 0.501) Hungary United States 0.276 (0.178, 0.374)
United States Ireland 0.051 (−0.049, 0.152) Ireland United States 0.002 (−0.095, 0.100)
United States Italy 0.368 (0.266, 0.471) Italy United States 0.303 (0.206, 0.399)
United States Malta 0.104 (−0.027, 0.235) Malta United States −0.067 (−0.202, 0.069)
United States Netherlands 0.198 (0.099, 0.297) Netherlands United States 0.140 (0.048, 0.233)
United States Poland 0.587 (0.485, 0.689) Poland United States 0.488 (0.388, 0.588)
United States Portugal 0.456 (0.358, 0.554) Portugal United States 0.342 (0.248, 0.436)
United States Romania 0.539 (0.435, 0.642) Romania United States 0.421 (0.317, 0.525)
United States Spain 0.479 (0.379, 0.579) Spain United States 0.402 (0.308, 0.496)
United States Sweden 0.248 (0.148, 0.348) Sweden United States 0.153 (0.060, 0.245)
Summary statistics:
Simple Trade-weighted
Median βTTIP:d prediction: 0.310 Median βTTIP:d prediction: 0.264
Mean βTTIP:d prediction: 0.302 Mean βTTIP:d prediction: 0.256
Standard deviation: 0.149 Standard deviation: 0.103

This table reports the predicted partial TTIP effects, βTTIP:d, for all pairs of countries affected by TTIP. The United Kingdom is not included in TTIP. Trade frictions between EU countries are assumed to not be affected. The numbers shown in parentheses are 95% confidence intervals. See text for further details.

What explains the diversity in predictions across the various pairs? It cannot be variation in bilateral distance, for instance, since all European countries are collectively separated from the U.S. by the Atlantic. Actually, the major source of heterogeneity across pairs is the first stage pair fixed effect, recovered from (10), representing ex ante trade frictions between the different potential TTIP pairings. Ireland, for example, is already very tightly integrated with the U.S. in trade: for Ireland-U.S. trade, we obtain an ex ante level of trade integration (i.e., iceberg frictions raised to the minus θ) between the U.S. and Ireland of dUS,IR¯−θ=0.027. While this may not, on the surface, seem like a large number, it is actually the largest of any U.S.-E.U. pair.44 The smallest trade cost index (0.001) is for the U.S.’s trade with Cyprus, along with, unsurprisingly, its trade with Bulgaria and Romania, followed closely by its trade with Poland (0.002).45

Turning to asymmetries, one might expect that, as the largest participant, the U.S. should have more “market power” ex ante with respect to its potential E.U. partners. Actually, because the E.U. countries are very tightly integrated with one another, their terms of tradeare significantly less sensitive to liberalizing with the U.S. than this logic would indicate. When we simulate the agreement using a common average effect, thelnToT^A:j we obtain for the U.S. is 0.0036, whereas the mean value we obtain for this index for the E.U. countries (0.0023) is actually lower, indicating a symmetric liberalization between the U.S. and E.U. actually tends to benefit the U.S. more than the E.U. As such, we infer that an “efficient agreement” would involve the E.U. countries granting relatively more concessions in this scenario. In addition, the fact that our coefficient on exporter GDP is slightly larger than that of importer GDP would also tend to favor the exports of the U.S., since it is the larger country in each pair.

For our general equilibrium predictions, we will stick with the simple trade model implied by (1) and (2). In particular, we will maintain that labor is the only factor of production and that trade takes place in final goods only. As shown in Head & Mayer (2014), imposing market clearing on a model of this type then delivers a standard general equilibrium system that generalizes across a wide range of different models. While this simple framework omits several factors that have been shown to be important for delivering larger gains from trade (e.g., multiple industries, trade in intermediates, dynamic effects, etc.), it is widely accepted in the literature as a benchmark for computing the general equilibrium effects of trade policies. Furthermore, it will allow us to capture the basic point that, even when an agreement has the same partial effect on all trade flows, general equilibrium outcomes can still be quite heterogeneous. The competitive equilibrium in such a model can be described by the following system of equations,

(18)wiLi=∑jπij⋅wjLj+Dj∀i,

where πij ≡ Aiwiθτijθ/Pjθ is the share of j’s total expenditure on goods produced in origin country i. Note that we allow trade to be unbalanced. Total expenditure in j is therefore comprised of an (endogenous) labor income term, wjLj, and an (exogenous) trade balanceterm Dj. According to (18), the total amount of output produced in origin iwiLi, must be equal to the sum of expenditure on goods produced in i across all destinations j.

Eq.(18) can be solved (in changes) to predict general equilibrium effects of an FTA on both welfare and trade as a result of an FTA. To see this, first let x^=x′/x denote the equilibrium change in a variable from an initial level x to a new equilibrium level x (i.e., the now-standard “hat algebra” notation of Dekle et al., 2007). The equilibrium in changes version of (18) is therefore:

(19)Yiw^i=w^i−θ∑jπij⋅τ^ij−θP^j−θ⋅Yjw^j+Dj∀i,

where P^j−θ can be computed as:

(20)P^j−θ=∑iπijw^i−θτ^ij−θ.

Given initial trade shares {πij}, output levels {Yi}, expenditure levels {Ej}, and a set of changes in trade barrier levels, {τ^ij−θ}, one can solve the system defined by (19) and (20) for the resulting changes in wages w^i. With wages in hand, we then obtain the following expressions for the associated general equilibrium changes in both welfare levels and trade flows:

(21)GEWelfareImpact:W^i=E^i/P^i
(22)GETradeImpact:X^ij=w^i−θτ^ij−θP^j−θ⋅E^j,

where the change in national expenditure, E^i, is computed as Yiw^i+Di/Ei.46 We will use the year 2006, the last year in our data, to compute the initial trade levels and trade balances.47 Finally, since (19) is non-linear in w^i, we require an assumption regarding the trade elasticityθ. Following the recommendations of Simonovska & Waugh (2014), we assume θ = 4.

Table 7 lists the predicted general equilibrium effects of TTIP, both for trade and for welfare, under the two noted scenarios. As is standard in this class of models, FTAs have a larger effect on trade flows than they do welfare, as the implied welfare cost of substituting to one’s own suppliers is usually relatively small.48 The U.S., for example, experiences a large change in trade volumes – including a 7.32% increase in the value of its exports – but only a 0.38% increase in its welfare, as buyer prices in the U.S. (i.e., PUS) rise at more or less the same rate as U.S. wages.

Table 7General Equilibrium Predictions for the Effects of an E.U./U.S. FTA.

  Percentage changes in trade and welfare, by country
“Average” Scenario “Heterogeneous” Scenario
Δ% Exports Δ% Imports Δ% Welfare Δ% Exports Δ% Imports Δ% Welfare
Austria 1.18 1.14 0.24 1.28 (0.93, 1.86) 1.23 (0.90, 1.79) 0.22 (0.17, 0.31)
Belgium-Luxembourg 1.58 1.59 0.20 1.19 (0.80, 1.88) 1.20 (0.81, 1.89) 0.12 (0.08, 0.20)
Bulgaria 0.81 0.59 0.06 1.71 (1.41, 2.33) 1.25 (1.03, 1.70) 0.14 (0.11, 0.20)
Canada −0.69 −0.67 −0.10 −0.81 (−1.24, −0.52) −0.78 (−1.20, −0.50) −0.10 (−0.15, −0.07)
Cyprus 0.74 0.20 0.02 0.88 (0.69, 1.26) 0.24 (0.19, 0.35) −0.02 (−0.08, 0.05)
Denmark 1.34 1.21 0.23 1.42 (1.04, 2.07) 1.28 (0.93, 1.86) 0.21 (0.17, 0.30)
Finland 1.34 1.60 0.20 1.48 (1.14, 2.11) 1.77 (1.36, 2.53) 0.21 (0.17, 0.29)
France 1.86 1.76 0.22 2.22 (1.69, 3.22) 2.10 (1.60, 3.04) 0.25 (0.19, 0.37)
Germany 1.90 2.59 0.36 1.98 (1.40, 3.03) 2.70 (1.90, 4.14) 0.37 (0.27, 0.57)
Greece 1.82 0.54 0.02 3.20 (2.64, 4.36) 0.96 (0.79, 1.30) 0.02 (−0.02, 0.08)
Hungary 0.72 0.70 0.11 1.07 (0.81, 1.53) 1.05 (0.80, 1.50) 0.15 (0.13, 0.20)
Iceland −0.45 −0.17 −0.06 −0.15 (−0.41, 0.07) −0.05 (−0.15, 0.03) −0.07 (−0.11, −0.04)
Ireland 2.62 4.54 1.35 0.26 (−0.47, 1.28) 0.46 (−0.81, 2.22) 0.13 (−0.24, 0.65)
Israel −0.57 −0.63 −0.06 −0.65 (−1.00, −0.42) −0.73 (−1.11, −0.47) −0.07 (−0.11, −0.05)
Italy 1.69 1.88 0.15 2.21 (1.71, 3.17) 2.44 (1.89, 3.51) 0.19 (0.15, 0.27)
Malta 2.06 1.23 0.29 0.26 (−0.43, 1.19) 0.15 (−0.26, 0.71) −0.09 (−0.18, 0.03)
Mexico −0.75 −0.75 −0.11 −0.91 (−1.41, −0.58) −0.90 (−1.39, −0.58) −0.12 (−0.18, −0.08)
Morocco −0.15 −0.08 −0.05 −0.05 (−0.21, 0.10) −0.03 (−0.11, 0.05) −0.07 (−0.10, −0.04)
Netherlands 1.58 1.60 0.54 1.02 (0.58, 1.70) 1.03 (0.59, 1.71) 0.29 (0.15, 0.52)
Norway −0.30 −0.18 −0.08 −0.18 (−0.34, −0.07) −0.11 (−0.21, −0.04) −0.08 (−0.13, −0.05)
Poland 0.71 0.58 0.04 1.78 (1.47, 2.40) 1.44 (1.19, 1.94) 0.13 (0.11, 0.18)
Portugal 1.35 0.94 0.09 2.33 (1.93, 3.17) 1.63 (1.35, 2.22) 0.15 (0.13, 0.20)
Romania 0.91 0.56 0.04 1.93 (1.59, 2.62) 1.20 (0.99, 1.63) 0.10 (0.07, 0.15)
Spain 1.27 0.88 0.07 2.39 (1.98, 3.24) 1.64 (1.36, 2.23) 0.13 (0.10, 0.18)
Sweden 1.58 1.99 0.33 1.21 (0.77, 1.93) 1.52 (0.97, 2.43) 0.23 (0.15, 0.38)
Switzerland −0.31 −0.32 −0.05 −0.25 (−0.40, −0.17) −0.26 (−0.42, −0.18) −0.05 (−0.07, −0.03)
Tunisia −0.07 −0.05 −0.06 0.05 (−0.13, 0.22) 0.03 (−0.09, 0.15) −0.08 (−0.12, −0.05)
Turkey −0.11 −0.08 −0.03 0.01 (−0.16, 0.16) 0.00 (−0.11, 0.11) −0.03 (−0.05, −0.02)
United Kingdom −0.28 −0.21 −0.05 −0.15 (−0.31, −0.03) −0.12 (−0.24, −0.02) −0.05 (−0.08, −0.03)
United States 7.32 4.33 0.38 6.49 (4.63, 9.96) 3.84 (2.74, 5.89) 0.37 (0.27, 0.55)
Other Non-TTIP −0.23 −0.29 −0.02 −0.23 (−0.34, −0.16) −0.29 (−0.43, −0.20) −0.02 (−0.03, −0.01)
EU 1.48 1.51 0.22 1.55 (1.09, 2.36) 1.58 (1.11, 2.40) 0.20 (0.13, 0.31)
TTIP 2.60 2.32 0.28 2.50 (1.77, 3.81) 2.23 (1.58, 3.41) 0.26 (0.19, 0.41)
Non-TTIP −0.30 −0.35 −0.03 −0.31 (−0.48, −0.21) −0.36 (−0.56, −0.24) −0.03 (−0.05, −0.02)
World 1.28 1.28 0.14 1.22 (0.75, 1.98) 1.22 (0.75, 1.98) 0.13 (0.08, 0.21)

This table compares the results from a general equilibrium simulation of the effects of a hypothetical U.S./E.U. FTA (“TTIP”) under two scenarios: (i) an “average” scenario, where all GE effects are predicted based off of a common average partial effect being applied equally to all TTIP pairs, and (ii) a “heterogeneous” scenario where we use heterogeneous partial effects predicted by our out-of-sample prediction model. For the latter set of results, we include bootstrapped 95% confidence intervals in parentheses. See text for further details.

Table 7 reveals several key insights we wish to focus on. First, even in the “average” scenario, where all TTIP pairs enjoy a common partial effect, the general equilibrium implications of TTIP introduce their own layer of heterogeneity. Usefully, this heterogeneity can largely be related back to a key aspect of our analysis, the level of ex ante trade frictions between countries. For example, the largest welfare effect is for Ireland, who enjoys a 1.35% increase in its welfare thanks to closer trade ties with the U.S. Intuitively, since Ireland already has the lowest ex ante trade barriers with the U.S., using a common partial effect for TTIP would eliminate a relatively larger portion of Ireland’s remaining trade frictions with the U.S. than those of other E.U. members.49 Similarly, the lowest welfare gainers under the average scenario include Cyprus, Bulgaria, Greece, Poland, and Romania— countries with which the U.S.’s ex ante trade relations are not as strong.

Of course, these same close relations between the U.S. and Ireland also led us to predict much smaller partial effects under the “heterogeneous” scenario. In turn, the subsequent welfare effect for Ireland is likewise predicted to be much smaller than that of the “average” scenario and is indistinguishable from zero based on the accompanying bootstrapped 95% confidence interval. The case of Ireland thus illustrates the following simple, powerful conclusion: low ex ante trade frictions are associated with both small partial effects ex postas well as larger welfare effects ex post. Therefore, using a common average partial effect will tend to systematically overestimate welfare gains for country-pairs who are already well-integrated in trade. A similar principle also applies in reverse. The Eastern European E.U. members Bulgaria, Hungary, Poland, and Romania are among those that see the largest improvements in welfare from introducing heterogeneous partial effects, reflecting the large partial effects we predicted for these countries in Table 6. For non-TTIP countries, general equilibrium effects are relatively similar across scenarios. As one would expect, these countries all experience mild trade diversion and most experience small welfare losses. The largest losers notably major regional trade partners on either side of the Atlantic not included in the agreement, such as the EFTA countries Norway, Iceland, and Switzerland, the U.S.’s NAFTA partners Canada and Mexico, as as well as the United Kingdom (owing to its presumed “Brexit” from the E.U.)

7. Conclusion

How do free trade agreements actually affect trade between member countries? And can we predict the impact of future agreements on member and non-member countries? This paper introduces a novel methodology intended to push forward our ability to answer each of these questions. Our approach not only allows us to shed light on several useful, intuitive determinants of the partial effects of FTAs, but also directly lends itself towards developing and validating an ex ante prediction model for predicting the effects of future agreements. Several notable aspects of the analysis include a novel set of theory-guided indices for predicting the magnitude of FTA partial effects, the ability to consider a wide variety of other possible sources of heterogeneity, and the opportunity to specifically examine determinants of heterogeneous partial effects within the same agreement.

Still, many relevant questions remain just beyond our current reach. For example, there remains only so much we can say about which FTAprovisions work in favor of creating trade versus inhibiting trade. It is also widely acknowledged that economic integration agreements have consequences for investment as well as trade. The consequences for investment, too, are likely very heterogeneous across agreements and may interact with the trade-creating effects of FTAs in ways we cannot capture in our current study. Furthermore, as shown in Anderson & Yotov (2016), FTAs can have very different effects across industries and these industry-level differences in turn have important consequences for quantifying the welfare impact of FTAs. Adapting our two stage procedure to a similar industry-level perspective would be a natural extension of our methods. Including trade in agricultural products and services would make for similar improvements, especially trade in services, since services are an increasingly important component of both world trade and the objectives of new trade agreements. As new data on trade in services as well as FDI are becoming increasingly available, incorporating these various important elements will make for valuable new avenues for future research.

Appendix A. Data Appendix

Table A.1. Included countries.

Main sample(52 countries/regions): Argentina, Australia, Austria, Bulgaria, Belgium-Luxembourg, Bolivia, Brazil, Canada, Switzerland, Chile, China, Colombia, Costa Rica, Cyprus, Germany, Denmark, Ecuador, Egypt, Spain, Finland, France, United Kingdom, Greece, Hungary, Indonesia, Ireland, Iceland, Israel, Italy, Jordan, Japan, South Korea, Kuwait, Morocco, Mexico, Malta, Myanmar, Malaysia, Netherlands, Norway, Philippines, Poland, Portugal, Qatar, Romania, Singapore, Sweden, Thailand, Tunisia, Turkey, Uruguay, United States.
Rest of World(17 countries/regions): Cameroon, Hong Kong, India, Iran, Kenya, Sri Lanka, Macau, Mauritius, Malawi, Niger, Nigeria, Nepal, Panama, Senegal, Trinidad & Tobago, Tanzania, South Africa.

Table A.2. Included agreements.

Multilateral trade blocs
Agreement Year Member Countries
ASEAN 2000 Indonesia, Malaysia, Myanmar, Philippines, Singapore, Thailand
Agadir 2006 Egypt, Jordan, Morocco, Tunisia
Andean Community  1993 Bolivia, Colombia, Ecuador
CEFTA 1993 Poland (1993–2004), Hungary (1993–2004), Romania (1997–2004), Bulgaria (1998–2004)
EFTA 1960 Norway, Switzerland, Iceland (1970), Portugal (1960–1986), Austria (1960–1995), Sweden (1960–1995) Finland (1986–1995).
EU  1958 Belgium-Luxembourg, France, Italy, Germany, Netherlands, Denmark (1973), Ireland (1973), United Kingdom (1973), Greece (1981), Portugal (1986), Spain (1986), Austria (1995), Finland (1995), Sweden (1995), Cyprus (2004), Malta (2004), Hungary (2004), Poland (2004)
Mercosur ∗† 1995 Argentina, Brazil, Uruguay
NAFTA 1994 Canada, Mexico, U.S.
Pan Arab Free Trade Area 1998 Egypt, Kuwait, Jordan, Morocco, Qatar, Tunisia

EFTA’s outside agreements: Turkey (1992), Bulgaria (1993), Hungary (1993), Israel (1993), Poland (1993), Romania (1993), Mexico (2000), Morocco (2000), Singapore (2003).

EU’s outside agreements: EFTA (1973), Cyprus (1988), Hungary (1994), Poland (1994), Bulgaria (1995), Romania (1995), Turkey (1996) , Tunisia (1998), Israel (2000), Mexico (2000), Morocco (2000),Chile (2003), Egypt (2004).

Other agreements: Australia-Singapore (2003), Australia-Thailand (2005), Australia-U.S. (2005), Bulgaria-Israel (2002), Bulgaria-Turkey (1998), Canada-Chile (1997), Canada-Costa Rica (2003), Canada-Israel (1997), Canada-U.S. (1989), Chile-China (2006), Chile-Costa Rica (2002), Chile-Mexico (1999), Chile-Singapore (2006), Chile-South Korea (2004), Chile-U.S. (2004), Colombia-Mexico (1995), Costa Rica-Mexico (1995), Egypt-Turkey (2006), Hungary-Israel (1998), Hungary-Turkey (1998), Israel-Mexico (2000), Israel-Poland (1998), Israel-Romania (2001), Israel-Turkey (2001), Japan-Mexico (2005), Jordan-U.S. (2002), Mercosur-Andean (2005), Mercosur-Bolivia (1996), Mercosur-Chile (1996), Mexico-Uruguay (2005), Morocco-U.S. (2006), Poland-Turkey (2000), Romania-Turkey (1998), Singapore-U.S. (2004), Tunisia-Turkey (2006).

For these two blocs, we follow the NSF-Kellogg Database in using, respectively, the date at which ASEAN “moved towards” becoming a free trade area and the date at which Mercosur became a customs union.

Denotes a deeper level of agreement (e.g., a customs union).

Appendix B. Supplementary data

 

References

To view the original paper, please click here.

Copyright © 2018 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.